Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Psychol., 01 December 2022
Sec. Organizational Psychology
This article is part of the Research Topic Unraveling the Role of Psychological Capital on Innovation from the Knowledge Management Perspective View all 14 articles

Impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage in China: The moderating role of policy incentives and market competition

\r\nLin RenLin Ren1Dan LiuDan Liu2Deping Xiong*Deping Xiong1*
  • 1School of Finance, Yunnan University of Finance and Economics, Kunming, China
  • 2School of Economics, Yunnan University of Finance and Economics, Kunming, China

Due to its capital-related nature, corporate leverage is highly exposed to financial risk, and optimizing corporate leverage is an effective method of mitigating financial risk to maximize corporate value. We use a two-way fixed effects model to examine the impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage using panel data of A-share listed companies in the Chinese manufacturing sector from 2012 to 2020. The results show that technological innovation and corporate leverage exhibit significant heterogeneity in cross-sectional, spatial and temporal dimensions. By further distinguishing between the effects of policy incentives and market competition, we find that the former exerts an “investment crowding out” effect and the latter an “innovation spillover” effect. These factors mitigate the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. In general, this study provides empirical evidence for the rational allocation of resources by the Chinese government, the development of innovation capabilities, and the adjustment of leverage by firms from various regions.

Introduction

As financial markets have developed rapidly, leveraged operations and expansion have become a global trend among corporations. For example, at one point, China’s non-financial corporate sector leverage ratio had risen to 272.5%, exceeding not only emerging economies but also developed economies such as the United States, Europe, and Japan. In a market economy, it makes sense for businesses to use external funding for operations and expansion. However, issues such as diminishing marginal benefits of corporate investment increased risk of default, and erosion of corporate performance due to over-leverage have become insurmountable business obstacles for businesses (Campello, 2006; Berk et al., 2010; Reinhart and Rogoff, 2010; Schularick and Taylor, 2012). Consequently, corporate leverage adjustment is widely adopted and utilized.

Following the theory of trade-offs, corporate leverage adjustment assists firms in coping with various risks arising from uncertainty and maximizes corporate value by achieving the desired capital structure. The empirical study demonstrates that firm heterogeneity and asymmetry result in different leverage adjustment costs at different leverage levels. The leverage effect is only triggered when firms’ profitability is sufficient to cover the adjustment costs (Aivazian et al., 2005; Galvao and Montes-Rojas, 2010). Consequently, corporate leverage adjustment is viable for companies to deal with uncertainty and attain their desired capital structure. Additional research into corporate leverage factors is necessary to achieve sustainable corporate growth.

Schumpeter’s concepts of “creative destruction” and “creative accumulation” concerning corporate innovation hold that innovation can be used as a new production function by altering the original conditions of production or by adding new factors of production to form a new system, thereby becoming a force for sustained economic growth. Moreover, according to research, technological innovation determines a company’s market value, comparative advantage, and return on investment, which is crucial for competitiveness, survival, and sustainable development (Myers, 1977; Porter, 1992). Therefore, technological innovation presents an opportunity for corporate leverage.

In China, the pattern of economic growth is shifting from factor-driven to technology-driven, and technological innovation has emerged as a determining factor for high-quality economic development. In the 14th 5-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development and the 2035 Vision Plan (effective 2021), the Chinese government has proposed to improve the national innovation system and promote the concentration of various innovation factors in Chinese enterprises. At the firm level, innovative firms are the foundation for developing an innovative nation, and Chinese firms must enhance their market competitiveness by developing innovative products and services (Lee et al., 2021). On the one hand, they must manage their financial risks and continually optimize their leverage to maximize their company’s value. Notably, as Chinese firms have gradually shifted their innovation financing from a high reliance on foreign capital and international trade to domestic investment and government-subsidized innovation, this shift has had a unique effect on the relationship between technological innovation and firm leverage in Chinese firms. China is worth studying as an example of significant market failures and government interventions in emerging economies.

From 2012 to 2020, we empirically examine the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage using the financial data of A-share listed companies on China’s Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges. The two variables have a significant negative correlation. By distinguishing further between the effects of policy incentives and market competition, we find that policy incentives have an “investment crowding out” effect. In contrast, market competition has an “innovation spillover” effect. These factors mitigate the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. In addition, the relationship between the two is influenced by the nature of the firm, industry characteristics, location, and the firm’s life cycle.

Our research makes the following contributions: First, the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage is reconsidered. In contrast to answering the question of what types of corporations are conducive to innovation (He and Tian, 2013; Hsu et al., 2014; Cornaggia et al., 2015; Iqbal et al., 2022), the purpose of this study is to determine whether technological innovation can drive corporate leverage adjustment. Second, we investigate the effect of policy incentives and market competition on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. On this basis, we also observe regional differences to make the study more realistic. Thirdly, we contribute to the existing literature on corporate leverage by investigating the various effects of technological innovation on corporate leverage through cross-sectional, spatial, temporal, and leverage interval differentiation.

The remainder of the article is structured as follows: Section “Hypothesis development” is devoted to the formulation of hypotheses, Section “Data and methods” to the description of data and methods, Section “Analysis results” to the analysis results, Section “Robustness tests” to robustness tests, and Section “Conclusion” to the conclusion.

Hypothesis development

Capital structure theory has become one of the most exciting areas of study in finance due to its unique insights into various issues about corporate leverage and firm value, as well as its vast and far-reaching implications for corporate financing decisions (Ma, 2021). It clarifies the significance of debt in the capital structure of a company. Companies no longer merely leverage users, but leverage designers, making selective and targeted adjustments to maximize company value and balance the internal and external environments.

Previous research on corporate leverage has generally focused on external (“taxation,” “bankruptcy”) and internal (“information transmission,” “agency costs”) factors, such as the cost of leverage adjustment, the soft budget constraint, the level of government control, the marketization process, policy influences, economic cycles, financial crises, and product market competition (MacKay and Phillips, 2005; Faulkender et al., 2012; Tsoy and Heshmati, 2017). However, the impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage has received scant attention.

Technological innovation and corporate leverage

Early research on corporate leverage appeared unrelated to the firm’s value, as they did not consider the insolvency risk. Nevertheless, according to trade-off theory, during an economic downturn, financial crisis and bankruptcy risks force a firm’s market value into a paradox of “increased debt” and “financial risk” because of both its operating performance and the external environment (e.g., an infectious disease pandemic or loose monetary policy). A firm’s leverage can vary from its target capital structure. To maximize corporate value, additional adjustments to corporate leverage are necessary. Nonetheless, because the cost of adjustment exceeds its benefit, some businesses lack the incentive to leverage adjustment, which is detrimental to the interests of shareholders and severely restricts the development of the business (Fischer et al., 1989; Leary and Roberts, 2005; Ogawa, 2007; Strebulaev, 2007; Cook and Tang, 2010; Li et al., 2017). Consequently, it is necessary to elaborate on the factors driving the leverage adjustment.

In addition to influencing the sustainability of corporations, technological innovation integrates internal and external resources to spur environmental innovation (Horbach, 2008; Cai and Zhou, 2014). As a result, several academics have pondered whether technological innovation can facilitate corporate leverage adjustment. Some academics contend that technological innovation produces an innovative performance that drives rapid firm growth and has a tax shield effect that reduces financing costs. Therefore, technological innovation is having a deleveraging impact, which means that the more firms focus on innovation, the less debt they carry (Del Canto and Suarez Gonzalez, 1999; Graham, 2003; Graham and Tucker, 2006; Honore et al., 2015). Others contend that the opposite is true. They conclude that firms’ technological innovation capabilities are positively related to their debt levels because they are more willing to leverage and have higher debt levels because of the inherent consistency of their technological innovation goals, which reduce innovation risk and increase financial risk tolerance (David et al., 2000).

Indeed, technological innovation has two significant effects on corporate leverage: externally, by enhancing product market competitiveness, and internally, by strengthening corporate governance capabilities. These effects manifest themselves in sustained excess profits and industry-specific advantages. Because capital structure can reflect product market expectations of future competition, particularly for overleveraged firms, product market competition can force technological innovation and adjust leverage through monopoly rents and profits from intellectual property (e.g., patents) (Brander and Lewis, 1986; Showaher, 1995). In addition, technological innovation can help firms engage in capacity governance. These include creating differentiated new demand, transforming excess capacity into efficient capacity, and further optimizing distorted firm leverage by offsetting the cost of firm recapitalization with higher marginal product returns (Liu and Huang, 2016).

Consequently, based on the analysis presented above, we propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Technological innovation has a negative correlation with corporate leverage.

Impact of policy incentives

Since technological innovation is a high-investment, long-cycle, and high-risk behavior, decision-makers neglect to invest in innovation when debt financing creates a constraint on free cash flow to maximize shareholders’ interests promptly (Jensen, 1986). In addition, because technological innovation involves patent protection and externality risks, corporations’ exogenous financing becomes extra cautious, discouraging R&D investment (Galende Del Canto and Suarez Gonzalez, 1999). Therefore, most technological innovation requires policy incentives.

Policy incentives are government interventions to redistribute resources in a market economy, avoiding value transfer caused by interest payments by reducing the cash consumption of technological innovation by businesses to stimulate technological innovation via direct or indirect policy assistance. Government subsidies, tax incentives, inter-institutional cooperation, and others are the primary policy incentives (Spence, 1984; David et al., 2000; Giudici and Paleari, 2000; Nishimura and Okamur, 2011). As China’s institutional development continues to advance, the government, as an innovation policymaker and strategist, is very concerned with fostering technological innovation in businesses by formulating pertinent policies. Nevertheless, due to the uncoordinated and uneven regional economic development, policy incentives in China may result in regional disparities.

Numerous studies have confirmed the correlation between policy incentives and the technological innovation of businesses. Positive studies indicate that policy incentives not only alleviate the financing constraints associated with technological innovation and effectively promote R&D in high-precision end technologies but also regulate firms’ cost, equity, and R&D budgets, with the potential to improve firms’ capital structure (Honore et al., 2015; Xia and Roper, 2016; Howell, 2017; Li et al., 2017; Wade, 2017; Chen et al., 2020). Consequently, in terms of the direct effects of policy incentives, firms that receive government assistance always receive more funding, greater tax benefits, an increase in innovation output, and an improvement in innovation performance in their innovation investments (Gonzalez et al., 2005). On the other hand, pessimistic studies contend that policy incentives can lead to a decline in the quality of corporate R&D, R&D investment crowding out, corruption and rent-seeking, and a distortion of the policy’s original intent (Belenzon and Berkovitz, 2010; Bernini and Pellegrini, 2011; Lee, 2011; Liu et al., 2019; Kong, 2020). Therefore, one cannot ignore the indirect effects of policy incentives.

First, policy incentives can have an “investment crowding out” effect on firms’ technological innovation. Firms may reduce their innovation investment to seek policy support and restructure their technological innovation projects, substituting long-term quality innovation with simple short-term innovation, resulting in the innovation of lower quality (Wallsten, 2000; Czarnitzki et al., 2011; Aghion et al., 2013; Stuart and Wang, 2016). Second, according to signaling theory, obtaining policy support can help firms send positive signals, causing investors to anticipate that the firm is undervalued and to readily attract lower-cost external financing, which may contribute to the increase in firm leverage (Takalo and Tanayama, 2010).

Based on the analysis presented above, we propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2 (H2). The negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage is weakened by policy incentives.

Impact of market competition

The study of firm leverage must pay close attention to the market competition of firms (Barton and Gordon, 1988; O’ Brien, 2003). Debt’s purpose is to give managers an incentive to manage more efficiently and reduce discretionary cash outlays that are not in the shareholders’ best interests. However, managers make decisions regarding leverage based on the firm’s competitive environment, which also reflects the firm’s industry (Williamson, 1963). As a result, competition can serve as an alternative to debt, limiting managers’ use of available cash flow. The greater the market competition, the greater the number of customer comparisons and options and the lower the firm’s excess returns. It is no longer advantageous for firms to increase their leverage, while it also exposes them to greater risk and uncertain outcomes (Williamson, 1975; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Kohli and Jaworski, 1990; Botosan and Plumlee, 2005). With increased market competition, companies are consequently more cautious with leverage. It also suggests that firms tend to reduce their leverage as the market becomes more competitive, even without the influence of technological innovation.

In addition, because the external institutional environment influences technological innovation, market competition, a critical external governance mechanism, can be a good indicator of external environment changes (Torkkeli et al., 2019). According to the well-known “Schumpeter effect,” competition reduces firms’ excess profits, and monopoly is the most effective innovation driver. A high level of market competition increases the likelihood that innovation will be imitated or substituted, which tends to generate technological innovation spillover effects, resulting in a decline in innovation performance and discouraging firms from innovating. In other words, innovation declines as market competition rise (Schumpeter, 1942; Grossman and Helpman, 1993).

China’s reform and opening up have accelerated its marketization process. However, even though market mechanisms have been unleashed and have driven economic development, there is still the dilemma of significant differences in regional market competition and uncoordinated economic growth. On the one hand, regions with intense market competition exhibit a concentration of industry factors, resulting in “innovation spillover,” which deprives the private sector of the incentive to innovate. On the other hand, most of the leverage in China’s manufacturing sector is held by state-owned enterprises (SOEs), whose proximity to the government grants them access to exogenous financing, promoting higher leverage.

Considering the above analysis, market competition may dampen the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. We propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3 (H3). The negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage is weakened by market competition.

Data and methods

Data

Our initial sample consists of China’s A-share-listed manufacturing companies. The sample period spans 2012 through 2020. In addition, the China Stock Market & Accounting Research Database (CSMAR) and the East Money Data Platform provide information on the key independent variable, technological innovation (CHOICE). The remaining data comes from financial reports of publicly traded companies and the National Bureau of Statistics of China’s website.

The initial sample is screened based on the following four criteria: (1) the exclusion of companies designated as special treatment (ST) or special transfer (PT) during the sample period; (2) the removal of post-2012 listings; (3) the exclusion of companies with missing data during the sample period; and (4) the exclusion of companies with abnormal financial conditions, such as gross assets below zero and gearing below or above one. In addition, we eliminate the top and bottom 1% of each variable’s data set to avoid estimation bias. After completing the preceding steps, we obtained 8,841 valid sample observations.

Variable definition

Corporate leverage

This study’s dependent variable is corporate leverage. Observing the change in corporate leverage reveals the adjustment pattern of corporate leverage. According to empirical studies, book value is favored over market value when discussing financial leverage (Stonehill et al., 1974). Therefore, corporate leverage is defined as the ratio of total debt to the book value of total assets.

Technological innovation

In this study, the independent variable is technological innovation. In this paper, technological innovation refers to technological innovation at the firm level, where a company creates a new product, offers a new service, or implements a new process. To reduce noise in measuring technological innovation, we introduce innovation intensity, which uses the ratio of R&D expenditures to operating revenue to measure corporations’ technological innovation (Nosheen et al., 2016).

Control variables

We control the size (Size), Return on Net Assets (ROE), Year-on-Year Growth Rate of Operating Income (Gro_oper), Financial Expenses (Debt), Liquidity of Assets (Liq_ass), and Corporate Age (Age) (Ramaswamy, 2001; Frank and Goyal, 2003; Mithas et al., 2012; Lusardi and Tufano, 2015; Klobucar and Orsag, 2019; Berger et al., 2022). The definitions and descriptive statistics for these variables are provided in Table 1.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Table 1. Definitions of the variables.

Moderating variables

We utilized policy incentives and market competition to moderate the relationship between technological innovation and firm leverage. The China Marketization Index is used as a proxy variable for market competition, while government subsidies are used as a proxy variable for policy incentives. In place of specific government subsidy data, this study uses government subsidies in the income statements of publicly traded corporations divided by total assets (Jia et al., 2021). In addition, the China Marketization Index utilized in this paper is derived from Wang et al.’s (2019) “China Provincial Marketization Index Report,” which began in 1997 and has since published nine reports covering 31 provinces in China. These reports include government-market relations, the development of the non-state economy, the development of product markets, the development of factor markets, the development of market intermediary organizations, and the rule of law environment. It consists of seventeen fundamental indices in five areas and is a comprehensive index that can more accurately reflect marketization. As the index is only updated to 2019, the data for this analysis spans 2012 through 2019.

Methods

The following empirical model was developed to examine the impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage.

L ev i , t = α + β × R & D i , t + θ × C o n t r o l i , t + ω i + δ t + ξ i , t (1)

The subscripts i and t represent firms and years, respectively. Levi,t represents corporate leverage while R&Di,t represents innovation intensity. Controli,t represent the multiple control variables. In this study, we also control for year fixed effectsδt and firm fixed effects δi. To investigate further the impact of policy incentives and market competition on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage, we augment models (2) and (3) with interaction terms.

L ev i , t = α 0 + α 1 × R & D i , t + β 1
× G over i , t + β 2 × R & D i , t × G over i , t + θ
× C o n t r o l i , t + ω i + δ t + ξ i , t (2)
L ev i , t = α 0 + α 1 × R & D i , t + β 1 × Market i , t + β 2 × R & D i , t
× Market i , t + θ × C o n t r o l i , t + ω i + δ t + ξ i , t (3)

Goveri,t and Marketi,t are measures of policy incentives and market competition, R&Di,t × Goveri,t denotes the moderating effect of policy incentives on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage, and R&Di,t × Marketi,t denotes the moderating effect of market competition on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage.

Analysis results

Statistical analysis

Descriptive statistics

Table 2 displays descriptive statistics for the most critical variables. Based on the average leverage value, Chinese manufacturing companies’ average annual leverage ratio was 0.401. Regarding the leverage structure, short-term leverage accounted for 83.8%, and long-term leverage accounted for 16.2%, indicating that the sample manufacturing enterprises’ debt financing was primarily short-term. The range of technological innovation values is from 0.001 to 0.198, with a mean, standard deviation, and median of 0.042, 0.029, and 0.037, respectively, indicating that corporations vary widely in terms of innovation intensity, but the majority are also incompetent. Also included in Table 2 are summary statistics for our control variables.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the variables.

Correlation coefficient test

The correlation coefficient between corporate technical innovation and corporate leverage is negative, as demonstrated in Table 3.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

Table 3. Pearson correlation coefficients of the variables.

Baseline result

The impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage is examined in Table 4. Column (1) does not include control variables. The coefficient on technological innovation is negative and statistically significant (–0.596, p-value < 0.01), according to the regression results. In column (2), which contains the independent variables, the technological innovation coefficient remains negative and statistically significant (–0.412, p-value < 0.01). Our findings concur with national studies (Singh and Faircloth, 2005; Min and Smyth, 2016). It supports H1, in which technological innovation correlates negatively with corporate leverage.

TABLE 4
www.frontiersin.org

Table 4. Impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage.

First, the tax shield effect of leverage provides a broader scope for technological innovation and cheaper financial support through profitability signals (Brown and Petersen, 2011). Second, technological innovation increases firms’ productivity and facilitates their rapid growth. Third, it increases the industry’s competitiveness and market share and can motivate the firm to adjust its leverage to achieve its desired capital structure (Ciftci and Cready, 2011). Fourth, incentives for technological innovation can also reduce firms’ innovation expenses and boost their profitability (Czarnitzki and Licht, 2006; Hewitt-Dundas and Roper, 2010). Lastly, from the perspective of the relationship between excess capacity and distortionary leverage, technological innovation assists firms in governing their capacity, enables them to increase profits despite excess capacity, and shifts their leverage toward an optimal band (Almeida and Campello, 2007; Yu, 2017).

Impact of policy incentives

The effect of policy incentives on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage is then investigated. In column (1) of Table 5, the effects of policy incentives are detailed. Before constructing the interaction terms, all variables are centralized to prevent multicollinearity issues. Column (1) demonstrates that the coefficient on technological innovation is significantly negative at the 1% level. In comparison, the coefficient on the interaction term between government subsidies and innovation intensity is significantly positive at the 5% level, suggesting that policy incentives have a dampening effect on them, which supports the hypothesis of H2 that policy incentives weaken the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage.

TABLE 5
www.frontiersin.org

Table 5. Impact of policy incentives and market competition on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage.

The possible explanation is that, contrary to positive intuition, while the direct effect of policy incentives makes firms more innovative. The indirect effect of policy incentives also has an “investment crowding out” effect on firms’ technological innovation. As observed, China’s manufacturing sector is more consistent with the “investment crowding out” effect. In previous studies, Liu et al. (2019) suggested the need for a more targeted use of government subsidies to incentivise firms to innovate.

Impact of market competition

To further examine the relationship between technological innovation and firm leverage, we incorporate market competition into the model. Column 2 of Table 5 reported the moderating effects of market competition. Controlling for other variables, the coefficient on technological innovation is significantly negative at the 5% level. In contrast, the coefficient on the interaction term between technological innovation and market competition is significantly positive at the 10% level, indicating that market competition mitigates the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. H3 is supported, i.e., market competition mitigates the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage.

The result can be explained by market competition’s “innovation spillover” effect. Specifically, the involuntary welfare spillover to peers and society, for which there is no return, undermines firms’ incentive to innovate. However, it should also be noted that in highly competitive markets, excessive competition can reduce firms’ excess profits, resulting in a greater emphasis on survival and a selective reduction in firms’ willingness to take risks and incentives to innovate (Schumpeter, 1942; Xie and Wei, 2016). Consequently, the impact of technological innovation on firms’ deleveraging can be moderated by market competition and is variable.

Further analysis

To observe additional regional heterogeneity in the moderating effect, we refer to the division of economic regions in the Opinions of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China and the State Council on Promoting the Rise of the Central Region and the Opinions of the State Council on the Implementation of Certain Policy Measures for the Development of the Western Region and divide them into three major economic regions for group regression: East, West and Central. The classifications are as follows: East: Beijing, Fujian, Guangdong, Hainan, Hebei, Jiangsu, Shandong, Shanghai, Tianjin, Zhejiang, Liaoning, Jilin, Heilongjiang; Central: Anhui, Henan, Hubei, Hunan, Jiangxi, Shanxi; West: Gansu, Guangxi, Guizhou, Inner Mongolia, Ningxia, Qinghai, Shaanxi, Sichuan, Tibet, Xinjiang, Yunnan, Chongqing.

The results of regional differentiation for the effects of policy incentives and market competition are presented in Tables 6, 7, respectively. The estimated results of the baseline regression are presented in columns (1), (2), and (3). Meanwhile, the regression of the moderating effects is presented in columns (4), (5), and (6). The coefficient on R&D in column (1) of Table 6 for the eastern region is significantly negative and statistically significant (–0.478, p-value < 0.01), indicating that technological innovation in the eastern region can effectively contribute to corporate deleveraging. The coefficient on Gover*R&D is statistically significant and significantly positive in column (4) of Table 6 (0.154, p-value < 0.1), and the coefficient on Market*R&D is statistically significant and significantly positive in column (4) of Table 7 (0.152, p-value < 0.05). It demonstrates that the east’s policy incentives and market competition mitigate the negative relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. The coefficient on R&D in column (3) of Table 6 is negative but not statistically significant; the coefficient on Gover*R&D in column (6) of Table 6 is significantly positive and statistically significant (0.343, p-value < 0.01), and the coefficient on Market*R&D in column (7) of Table 7 is significantly positive and statistically significant (0.266, p-value < 0.05). In other words, policy incentives and market competition dampen the technology innovation-corporate leverage relationship in the western region. The central region lacks a significant moderating effect.

TABLE 6
www.frontiersin.org

Table 6. A comparison of regression results on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage in different regions before and after the inclusion of policy incentives.

TABLE 7
www.frontiersin.org

Table 7. A comparison of regression results on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage in different regions before and after the inclusion of market competition.

In contrast to the negative relationship between technology innovation and corporate leverage in the benchmark regression, the coefficients on Gover*R&D and Market*R&D are significantly positive for both the eastern and western regions when the effects of policy incentives and market competition are accounted for. In addition, when both are present, the deleveraging effect of technological innovation in the western region changes from negligible to significant. Possible causes include the injection of political and economic dynamism into China’s western regions through strategies such as developing the west and revitalizing the countryside. In addition, it can effectively facilitate access to innovation support (e.g., policies, resources, technology) and cheaper funding for innovation projects (e.g., government grants, loans for inclusive finance projects) for businesses in the west. Therefore, it is implicitly a policy recommendation that continued improvements in the institutional and economic environment are more conducive to exploiting the adverse effects of technological innovation on corporate leverage.

Lastly, the insignificance of the central region may be due to the unbalanced development strategies implemented in China, such as priority development in the east, development in the west, and revitalization of old industrial bases, which have objectively created a “depression” in the macroeconomic pattern of the central region. It results in the total economic development of the central region being lower than that of the eastern region, and the growth rate of the central region is slower than that of the eastern region. As a result, the total economic development of the central region is lower than that of the eastern region, and the growth rate of economic development in the central region is lower than that of the western region.

Robustness tests

In this section, we conduct several checks on the reliability of our key findings.

IV regression results

We chose science expenditure as the instrumental variable to address the potential endogeneity issue. There are reasons for the selection of instrumental variables. Firstly, as regional science expenditure is macro-policy support, unlike profit-seeking firms on the market, the government intends to optimize the regional structure and will provide support to firms across the region without an explicit preference for supporting certain firms. Second, when GDP is the primary metric for measuring political performance, governments have a self-interested investment preference to favor production over innovation due to innovation’s long-term and unpredictable nature, resulting in a high degree of regional variation in science spending. Lastly, regional science expenditure typically reflects the level of support for innovation and the conditions for innovation that the region can provide to firms. It is closely related to the paper’s subject’s technological innovation. Table 8 displays the results of the two-stage least squares regression for the IV method, which indicates that technological innovation has a negative regression coefficient. The test results for the weak instrumental variables indicate that the F-statistic for the first stage is 65.29, which is well above the critical value of 10 for the weak instrumental variables (Hausman et al., 2005).

TABLE 8
www.frontiersin.org

Table 8. The results of the instrumental variables approach to regression.

Different model designs

We test the robustness of the model by substituting the proxy variables for technological innovation with one lag of technological innovation (L.R&D), one period of R&D expenditure taking the natural logarithm (Innov), and one period of lag R&D expenditure (L.Innov) while maintaining the original control variables. The regression results are in columns (1) through (3) of Table 9. After replacing the core explanatory variables in the benchmark model with each of the three new independent variables, we find that the coefficient on L.R&D is significantly negative at the 1% significance level in the two-fixed effects panel regression. At the same time, the coefficients on Innov and L.Innov are also significantly negative at the 5% significance level, respectively. In this instance, the negative effect of technological innovation on firm leverage is once more demonstrated.

TABLE 9
www.frontiersin.org

Table 9. The results of different models and variables.

Cross-sectional heterogeneity test

Different ownership

Table 10 shows the outcomes of grouped regressions by ownership and industry to determine under what conditions the impact of technological innovation on firm leverage would increase. Column (1) is for SOEs with a statistically significant negative coefficient on R&D (–0.476, p-value < 0.01); column (2) is for non-SOEs, with a statistically significant negative coefficient on R&D (–0.378, p-value < 0.01). (|–0.476| >|–0.378|) demonstrates that technological innovation negatively affects SOE leverage.

TABLE 10
www.frontiersin.org

Table 10. Cross-sectional analysis of ownership status and industry effects.

Two-thirds of the leverage in China’s non-financial sector is held by SOEs, and the leverage ratio of SOEs is growing faster than that of private enterprises, giving them more room for downward adjustment. Additionally, SOEs have stronger incentives and conditions for technological innovation because they must transform their production processes and optimize their production capacity through innovation. In addition, the Chinese government has advocated for the active participation of SOEs in technological innovation, resulting in an external effect-induced skewing of SOEs’ policies.

Different industries

Table 10, columns (3) and (4) display the results of regressions grouped by industry characteristics. The coefficient on R&D in high-tech industries is negative and statistically significant (–0.568, p-value < 0.01); the coefficient on R&D in traditional manufacturing industries is also negative and statistically significant (–0.338, p-value < 0.01). Our comparison reveals that the effect of technological innovation on deleveraging is significantly greater in high-tech industries than in traditional industries.

This difference may be attributed to the knowledge-intensive nature of high-tech industries, which necessitates efficient innovation for firms to gain market share rapidly. Despite the fiercer market competition, high-tech firms’ high innovation capacity can reduce innovation costs. As a result, decision-makers are more likely to invest more resources in innovation, rapidly increasing technological innovation and enhancing its deleveraging effect.

Different firm lifecycle stages

Our lifecycle classification is based on Dickinson’s cash flow-based method for determining the stage of a company’s lifecycle (Dickinson, 2006). In Table 11, we present the regression results for three different lifecycle firms to investigate the firm’s lifecycle impact. (The start-up period is excluded from the test because we are examining publicly traded corporations). In columns (1), (2), and (3), the coefficient on R&D is significantly negative and statistically significant (–0.318, p-value < 0.01), (–0.546, p-value < 0.01) and (–0.537, p-value < 0.01). It indicates that the negative effect of technological innovation on firm leverage persists regardless of the firm’s growth, maturity, or recessionary status. In |–0.546| >|–0.537| >|–0.318|, the period of maturity has the greatest effect, followed by the period of recession, and the period of growth has the least.

TABLE 11
www.frontiersin.org

Table 11. Impact analysis of business life cycle.

It may be because mature firms have greater profitability and market competitiveness, preparing them for deleveraging. In addition, firms with increasingly stable innovation resources can effectively increase their innovation success at a lower innovation cost, resulting in the greatest deleveraging effect of technological innovation on mature-stage businesses. In addition, possessing increasingly stable innovation resources can reduce innovation costs and increase a company’s innovation success rate. Therefore, firms can achieve the greatest deleveraging effect of technological innovation at the mature stage.

Different leverage intervals

In Table 12, we present the regression results for the low and high-leverage intervals to investigate the effect of technological innovation on the various leverage intervals. The R&D coefficients in columns (1) and (2) are both significantly negative and statistically significant (–0.337, p-value < 0.01) and (–0.212, p-value < 0.1). It indicates that low and high-leverage firms can deleverage through technological innovation, further supporting our findings.

TABLE 12
www.frontiersin.org

Table 12. Impact analysis of different leverage intervals.

Conclusion

Due to its capital-related nature, corporate leverage is highly exposed to financial risk, and optimizing corporate leverage is an effective method of mitigating financial risk. We present new evidence on the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage using China-specific data. Unlike previous research, this study investigates technological innovation while considering the effects of policy incentives and market competition. The relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage is generally negative. Simultaneously, they exhibit significant cross-sectional, spatial, and temporal heterogeneity. Furthermore, policy incentives produce an “investment crowding out” effect, whereas market competition produces an “innovation spillover” effect. Both factors inhibit the relationship between technological innovation and corporate leverage. Further differentiating by region, it is observed that both policy incentives and market competition in the eastern and western regions can have a significant negative moderating effect on the relationship between technology innovation and corporate leverage.

The effectiveness of China’s Structural Deleveraging Policy and National Innovation Strategy is reflected in our analysis. Technological innovation plays a significant role in the adjustment of corporate leverage. By encouraging firms to engage in technological innovation, policymakers in emerging economies can maximize corporate leverage levels. The heterogeneity tests also indicate that by actively guiding state-owned firms, high-technology firms, and mature firms toward technological innovation, governments can improve the efficiency of firms’ leverage adjustment, increase their investment in innovation, and decrease their reliance on low-end products. Moreover, continued focus on and improvement of the policy, investment, and legal environments can better leverage the moderating effect of technological innovation on corporate leverage.

Our study has some limitations. In the first place, when measuring technological innovation, we have only considered innovation inputs. Other factors, such as innovation output and efficiency, should also be considered. Second, due to our reliance on financial data, we have yet to measure the regional impact of technological innovation. Future research will expand the measurement of spatial spillover effects. In addition, the response of firm leverage to technological innovation is influenced by various factors, such as financial inclusion and emergencies, all of which merit further investigation in future studies.

Data availability statement

The original data supporting the conclusions of this article will be provided by the corresponding author.

Author contributions

DX developed the theoretical framework. DL worked on data analysis. LR worked on literature review and manuscript writing. All authors contributed to the article and approved the submitted version.

Funding

The authors acknowledged the financial support from the Science Foundation of Ministry of Education of China project (19YJC630136).

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Aghion, P., Van Reenen, J., and Zingales, L. (2013). Innovation and institutional ownership. Am. Econ. Rev. 103, 277–304. doi: 10.1257/aer.103.1.277

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Aivazian, V. A., Ge, Y., and Qiu, J. P. (2005). The impact of leverage on firm investment: Canadian evidence. J. Corp. Financ. 11, 277–291. doi: 10.1016/S0929-1199(03)00062-2

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Almeida, H., and Campello, M. (2007). Financial constraints, asset tangibility, and corporate investment. J. Finan. Stud. Rev. 20, 1429–1460. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhm019

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Barton, S. L., and Gordon, P. J. (1988). Corporate strategy and financial leverage. J. Strateg. Manage. 9, 623–632. doi: 10.1002/smj.4250090608

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Belenzon, S., and Berkovitz, T. (2010). Innovation in business groups. Manage. Sci. 56, 519–535. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1107

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Berger, A. N., Guedhami, O., Kim, H. H., and Li, X. M. (2022). Economic policy uncertainty and bank liquidity hoarding. J. Finance Intermed. 49, 100893.

Google Scholar

Berk, J. B., Stanton, R., and Zechner, J. (2010). Human Capital. bankruptcy, and capital structure. J. Finance 65, 891–926. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01556.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bernini, C., and Pellegrini, G. (2011). How are growth and productivity in private firms affected by public subsidy? Evidence from a regional policy. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 41, 253–265. doi: 10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2011.01.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Botosan, C. A., and Plumlee, M. A. (2005). Assessing alternative proxies for the expected risk premium. Account. Rev. 80, 21–53. doi: 10.2308/accr.2005.80.1.21

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Brander, J., and Lewis, T. (1986). Oligopoly and financial structure: The limited liability effect. Am. Econ. Rev. 76, 956–970.

Google Scholar

Brown, J. R., and Petersen, B. C. (2011). Cash holdings and R&D smoothing. J. Corp. Finance 17, 694–709. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.01.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cai, W. G., and Zhou, X. L. (2014). On the drivers of eco-innovation: Empirical evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 79, 239–248. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.05.035

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Campello, M. (2006). Debt financing: Does it boost or hurt firm performance in product markets? J. Financ. Econ. 82, 135–172. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.04.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chen, S. S., Chen, Y. S., Liang, W. L., and Wang, Y. Z. (2020). Public R&D spending and cross-sectional stock returns. Res. Policy 49:103887. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2019.103887

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ciftci, M., and Cready, W. M. (2011). Scale effects of R&D as reflected in earnings and returns. J. Account. Econ. 52, 62–80. doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.02.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cook, D. O., and Tang, T. (2010). Macroeconomic conditions and capital structure adjustment speed. J. Corp. Finance 16, 73–87. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2009.02.003

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cornaggia, J., Mao, Y. F., Tian, X., and Wolfe, B. (2015). Does banking competition affect innovation? J. Financ. Econ. 115, 189–209. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.09.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Czarnitzki, D., Hanel, P., and Rosa, J. M. (2011). Evaluating the impact of R&D tax credits on innovation: A microeconometric study on Canadian firms. Res. Pol. 40, 217–229.

Google Scholar

Czarnitzki, D., and Licht, G. (2006). Additionality of public R&D grants in a transition economy. Econ. Trans. 14, 101–131. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2006.00236.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

David, P. A., Hall, B. H., and Toole, A. A. (2000). Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric evidence. Res. Policy 29, 497–529. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00087-6

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Del Canto, J. G., and Suarez Gonzalez, I. (1999). A resource-based analysis of the factors determining a firm’s R&D activities. Res. Policy 28, 891–905. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00029-3

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dickinson, V. (2006). Future profitbility and the Role of Firm Life Cycle. Working paper. Gainesville, FL: University of Florida, 247–256.

Google Scholar

Faulkender, M., Flannery, M. J., Hankins, K. W., and Smith, J. M. (2012). Cash flows and leverage adjustments. J. Financ. Econ. 130, 632–646. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.10.013

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Fischer, E. O., Heinkel, R., and Zechner, J. (1989). Dynamic capital structure choice: Theory and tests. J. Finance 44, 19–40. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1989.tb02402.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Frank, M. Z., and Goyal, V. K. (2003). Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure. J. Financ. Econ. 67, 217–248. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(02)00252-0

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Galende Del Canto, J., and Suarez Gonzalez, I. (1999). A resource-based analysis of the factors determining a firm’s R&D Activities. Res. Policy 28, 891–905.

Google Scholar

Galvao, A. F., and Montes-Rojas, G. V. (2010). Penalized quantile regression for dynamic panel data. J. Stat. Plan. Infer. 140, 3476–3497. doi: 10.1016/j.jspi.2010.05.008

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Giudici, G., and Paleari, S. (2000). The provision of finance to innovation: A survey conducted among Italian technology-based small firms. Small Bus. Econ. 14, 37–53. doi: 10.1023/A:1008187416389

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gonzalez, X., Jaumandreu, J., and Pazo, C. (2005). Barriers to innovation and subsidy effectiveness. RAND J. Econ. 36, 930–950.

Google Scholar

Graham, J. R. (2003). Taxes and corporate finance: A review. Rev. Financ. Stud. 16, 1075–1129. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhg033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Graham, J. R., and Tucker, A. L. (2006). Tax shelters and corporate debt policy. J. Financ. Econ. 81, 563–594. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.09.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E. (1993). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Mit Press Books 1, 323–324.

Google Scholar

Hausman, J., Stock, J. H., and Yogo, M. (2005). Asymptotic properties of the Hahn-Hausman test for weak-instruments. Econ. Lett. 89, 333–342. doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2005.06.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

He, J., and Tian, X. (2013). The dark side of analyst coverage: The case of innovation. J. Financ. Econ. 109, 856–878. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.04.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hewitt-Dundas, N., and Roper, S. (2010). Output additionality of public support for innovation: Evidence for Irish manufacturing plants. Eur. Plan. Stud. 18, 107–122. doi: 10.1080/09654310903343559

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Honore, F., Munari, F., and de La Potterie, B. V. (2015). Corporate governance practices and companies’. R&D Intensity 44, 533–543. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2014.10.016

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Horbach, J. (2008). Determinants of environmental innovation - New evidence from German panel data sources. Res. Policy 37, 163–173. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2007.08.006

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Howell, S. T. (2017). Financing innovation: Evidence from R&D Grants. Am. Econ. Rev. 107, 1136–1164. doi: 10.1257/aer.20150808

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hsu, P. H., Tian, X., and Xu, Y. (2014). Financial development and innovation: Cross-country evidence. J. Financ. Econ. 112, 116–135. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.12.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Iqbal, N., Xu, J. F., Fareed, Z., Wan, G., and Ma, L. (2022). Financial leverage and corporate innovation in Chinese public-listed firms. Eur. J. Innov. Manag. 25, 299–323. doi: 10.1108/EJIM-04-2020-0161

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jensen, M. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. Am. Econ. Rev. 76, 323–329.

Google Scholar

Jensen, M. C., and Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the fifirm, managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. J. Financ. Econ. 3, 305–360. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jia, L. L., Nam, E., and Chun, D. (2021). Impact of Chinese government subsidies on enterprise innovation: Based on a three-dimensional perspective. Sustainability 13:1288. doi: 10.3390/su13031288

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Klobucar, D., and Orsag, S. (2019). Sustainable forest management for the future - the role of managerial economics and accounting. (Zagreb: University of Zagreb), 353–361.

Google Scholar

Kohli, A. K., and Jaworski, B. J. (1990). Market orientation: The construct, research propositions, and managerial implications. J. Mark. 54, 1–18. doi: 10.1177/002224299005400201

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kong, L. (2020). Government spending and corporate innovation. Manage. Sci. 66, 1584–1604. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2018.3252

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Leary, M. T., and Roberts, M. R. (2005). Do firms rebalance their capital structures? J. Finance 60, 2575–2619. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00811.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lee, C. Y. (2011). The differential effects of public R&D support on firm R&D: Theory and evidence from multi-country data. Technovation 31, 256–269. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2011.01.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lee, I. H., Kim, S. M., and Green, S. (2021). Social enterprises and market performance: The moderating roles of innovativeness, sectoral alignment, and geographic localization*. J. Bus. Res. 132, 491–506. doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2021.04.033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, W. F., Wu, C., Xu, L. P., and Tang, Q. Q. (2017). Bank connections and the speed of leverage adjustment: Evidence from China’s listed firms. Account. Finance 57, 1349–1381. doi: 10.1111/acfi.12332

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, D. Y., Chen, T., Liu, X. Y., and Yu, Y. Z. (2019). Do more subsidies promote greater innovation? Evidence from the Chinese electronic manufacturing industry. Econ. Model. 80, 441–452. doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2018.11.027

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, Q. R., and Huang, J. C. (2016). How does product innovation affect firm’s markup. J. World Econ. 11, 28–53.

Google Scholar

Lusardi, A., and Tufano, P. (2015). Debt literacy, financial experiences, and overindebtedness. J. Pension Econ. Finance 14, 332–368. doi: 10.1017/S1474747215000232

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ma, G. Q. (2021). Financial theory and policy. Shanghai: Fudan University Press.

Google Scholar

MacKay, P., and Phillips, G. M. (2005). How does industry affect firm financial structure? Rev. Financ. Stud. 18, 1433–1466. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhi032

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Min, B. S., and Smyth, R. (2016). How does leverage affect R&D intensity and how does R&D intensity impact on firm value in South Korea? Appl. Econ. 48, 5667–5675. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2016.1181836

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mithas, S., Tafti, A., Bardhan, I., and Goh, J. M. (2012). Information technology and firm profitability: Mechanisms and empirical evidence. MIS Q. 36, 205–224. doi: 10.2307/41410414

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. J. Financ Econ. 5, 147–175.

Google Scholar

Nishimura, J., and Okamur, H. (2011). Subsidy and networking: The effects of direct and indirect support programs of the cluster policy. Res. Pol. 40, 714–727.

Google Scholar

Nosheen, S., Sadiq, R., and Rafay, A. (2016). “The Primacy of Innovation in Strategic Financial Management-Understanding the Impact of Innovation and Performance on Capital Structure,” in International Conference on Management of Innovation and Technology (Icmit), 280–285. doi: 10.1109/ICMIT.2016.7605048

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

O’ Brien, J. P. (2003). The capital structure implications of pursuing a strategy of innovation. Strateg. Manage. J. 24, 415–431. doi: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2021.e07599

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ogawa, K. (2007). R&D investment and technological progress: A panel study of Japanese manufacturing firms’ behavior during the 1990s. J. Jpn. Int. Econ. 21, 403–423. doi: 10.1016/j.jjie.2007.02.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Porter, M. E. (1992). Capital disadvantage: America’s failing capital investment system. Harvard Bus. Rev. 70, 65–82.

Google Scholar

Ramaswamy, K. (2001). Organizational ownership, competitive intensity, and firm performance: An empirical study of the Indian manufacturing sector. Strateg, Manage. J. 22, 989–998.

Google Scholar

Reinhart, C. M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2010). Growth in a time of debt. Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 573–578. doi: 10.1257/aer.100.2.573

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Schularick, M., and Taylor, A. M. (2012). Credit booms gone bust: Monetary policy, leverage cycles, and financial crises, 1870-2008. Am. Econ. Rev. 102, 1029–1061. doi: 10.1257/aer.102.2.1029

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). The theory of competitive price. Amer. Econ. Rev. 32, 844–847.

Google Scholar

Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. University of illinois at urbana-champaign’s academy for entrepreneurial leadership historical research reference in entrepreneurship. Available online at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1496200

Google Scholar

Showaher, D. (1995). Oligopoly and financial structure: Comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 85, 647–654.

PubMed Abstract | Google Scholar

Singh, M., and Faircloth, S. (2005). The impact of corporate debt on long term investment and firm performance. Appl. Econ. 37, 875–883. doi: 10.1080/00036840500076762

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Spence, M. (1984). Cost reduction, competition, and industry performance. Econometrica 52, 101–121.

Google Scholar

Stonehill, T. N. A., Remmers, L., Wright, R., and Beekhuisen, T. (1974). Comparative international study of growth, profitability, and risk as determinants of corporate debt ratios in the manufacturing sector. J. Finance Quant. Anal. 9, 875–886. doi: 10.2307/2329684

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Strebulaev, I. A. (2007). Do tests of capital structure theory mean what they say? J. Finance 62, 1747–1787.

Google Scholar

Stuart, T., and Wang, Y. B. (2016). Who cooks the books in China, and does it pay? Evidence from private, high-technology firms. Strateg. Manage. J. 37, 2658–2676.

Google Scholar

Takalo, T., and Tanayama, T. (2010). Adverse selection and financing of innovation: Is there a need for R&D subsidies? J. Tech. Transfer 35, 16–41. doi: 10.1007/s10961-009-9112-8

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Torkkeli, L., Kuivalainen, O., Saarenketo, S., and Puumalainen, K. (2019). Institutional environment and network competence in successful SME internationalisation. Int. Market. Rev. 36, 31–55. doi: 10.1108/IMR-03-2017-0057

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tsoy, L., and Heshmati, A. (2017). Impact of financial crises on dynamics of capital structure:Evidence from Korean listed companies. IZA Discussion Paper No.10554. Bonn: IZA. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.2923637

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wade, R. H. (2017). The American paradox: Ideology of free markets and the hidden practice of directional thrust. Cambridge J. Econ. 41, 859–880. doi: 10.1093/cje/bew064

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wallsten, S. J. (2000). The effects of government-industry R&D programs on private R &D: The case of the small business innovation research program. RAND J. Econ. 31, 82–100.

Google Scholar

Wang, X. L., Fan, G., and Hu, L. P. (2019). Marketization Index of China’s Provinces; NERI Report 2018. Beijing: Social Science Academic Press.

Google Scholar

Williamson, O. E. (1963). “A model of rational managerial behaviour,” in A behavioural theory of the firm, eds R. M. Cyert and J. G. March (Englewook Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall).

Google Scholar

Williamson, O. E. (1975). Market and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York, NY: Free Press.

Google Scholar

Xia, T. J., and Roper, S. (2016). Unpacking open innovation: Absorptive capacity, exploratory and exploitative openness, and the growth of entrepreneurial biopharmaceutical firms. J. Small Bus Manage. 54, 931–952. doi: 10.1111/jsbm.12220

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xie, W. M., and Wei, H. Q. (2016). Market competition, organizational redundancy and enterprise R&D investment. China Soft Sci. 8, 102–111.

Google Scholar

Yu, B. (2017). Does technological innovation advance enterprise deleveraging? Transmission channel and acceleration mechanism. J. Financ. Econ. 113–127.

Google Scholar

Keywords: technological innovation, corporate leverage, policy incentives, market competition, China

Citation: Ren L, Liu D and Xiong D (2022) Impact of technological innovation on corporate leverage in China: The moderating role of policy incentives and market competition. Front. Psychol. 13:1068375. doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2022.1068375

Received: 12 October 2022; Accepted: 14 November 2022;
Published: 01 December 2022.

Edited by:

Yu Liping, Zhejiang Gongshang University, China

Reviewed by:

Yuxin Li, Shandong Institute of Business and Technology, China
Jin Chen, Kunming University of Science and Technology, China

Copyright © 2022 Ren, Liu and Xiong. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Deping Xiong, ksdream@126.com, xiongdeping@126.com

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.