Skip to main content

CONCEPTUAL ANALYSIS article

Front. Psychol., 20 October 2021
Sec. Organizational Psychology

How Is Knowledge Perceived as Power? A Multilevel Model of Knowledge Power in Innovation Networks

Chengqi Shi
Chengqi Shi*Fan ZhangFan ZhangPeiyao ZhuPeiyao ZhuQinlu ShiQinlu Shi
  • Shaanxi University of Science and Technology, Xi’an, China

Inter-organizational power relations have long been considered to be balanced in innovation networks, which are viewed as loosely coupled systems. Some recent studies, however, show that innovation networks are asymmetric and hierarchical, and the power of network actors has become a significant but rarely addressed issue. As knowledge is the most important resource in the network, this paper introduces the concept of knowledge power by combining related research perspectives and conducting some fundamental research on it as follows: (1) knowledge power’s origins are analyzed by proposing the term “activated knowledge” and studying the path through which it is formed over multiple levels of the network; (2) a multilevel framework of characteristics of activated knowledge, which is considered the major determinant of knowledge power, is established, and suggestions are offered for how they impact knowledge power; and (3) a multilevel measurement model for knowledge power is built, and the above propositions are tested by mathematical inference. The purpose of this paper is not only to study knowledge power’s formation, determinants, and measurement but also to offer a comprehensive view, combining multiple network levels and multiple research perspectives, that should be useful to researchers conducting future studies in this field.

Introduction

Networks are composed of inter-organizational relations. At present, the knowledge-based view (KBV) is an important framework for the study of inter-organizational relations (Ireland et al., 2002; Jha and Cottam, 2021) and continues to attract attention (Heiman and Nickerson, 2004; Quintane et al., 2011; Jordão, 2015; Lyu et al., 2020). In the KBV, network actors are viewed as knowledge sets in an innovation network, and the research focus is on individual organizations’ knowledge structures and intra- or inter-organizational knowledge transfers (Kim, 2015; Ouakouak et al., 2021). This trend, however, gives rise to the following problems: first, the current studies rarely combine resource dependencies based on the KBV with power mechanisms, although the interdependence of knowledge leads to power (Casciaro and Piskorski, 2005; Marjolein and Caniëls, 2009; Back and Kohtamäki, 2015) and power can be seen as a mechanism for achieving coordination and cooperation among network members (Oliver, 1991; Dhanaraj and Parkhe, 2006; Matheus et al., 2017). Second, innovation networks have multiple levels (Contractor et al., 2006; Provan et al., 2007; Matinheikki et al., 2017). The KBV mainly focuses on organizational knowledge characteristics and intra- or inter-organizational knowledge transfers (Lai et al., 2016) but neglects knowledge distribution over the whole network. Third, innovation networks are usually abstracted as knowledge networks (Samarra and Biggiero, 2008; Dantas and Bell, 2009) based on the KBV. This leads to research in this area that tends to emphasize organizational knowledge rather than individual organizations in the network and to ignore organizational strategic aims (Gilsing et al., 2007; An et al., 2021) and the role of network members (Na et al., 2020).

It is not enough to study innovation networks from the perspective of the KBV alone because knowledge and capabilities are both key elements of an enterprise (Santoro et al., 2021). Enterprises have many capabilities, among which dynamic capabilities are particularly important. The term “dynamic capability” (DC) refers to the renewal of resources and competencies to address changing environments (Eisenhardt and Martin, 2000). This term is, thus, closely related to the KBV and can also extend it, as many researchers find that DCs can have active impacts on enterprises in an innovation context. For example, DCs can influence firm performance through a variety of means and mechanisms (Torres et al., 2018; Prester et al., 2019; Ferreira et al., 2020). There are positive correlations between DCs and marketing capability, operation capability, and new product development performance (Mu, 2017); DCs can have a significant positive effect on short-term financial performance and long-term competitive advantage (Liu et al., 2019). In addition, existing research has also explored the application of DCs in different environments, such as the highly dynamic background of digital strategy (Yeow et al., 2018) and underlying organizational routines (Mousavi et al., 2018).

DCs can reflect an enterprise’s agency, but both knowledge and capability are limited as features of an individual organization. As a special networked form of organization, the innovation network falls somewhere between a market and a hierarchy and is often viewed as a collection of loosely coupled systems belonging to autonomous firms (Orton and Weick, 1990; Dhanaraj and Parkhe, 2006; Papadonikolaki, 2018; Su et al., 2021). Initiatives by members and interactions between members should be most emphasized. Studies in this field are generally based on the assumption that inter-organizational power relations are balanced and that there is equality between network actors. Some recent studies, however, show that innovation networks are asymmetric (Cowan and Jonard, 2009; Hao and Feng, 2018), with a pronounced hierarchical structure being observed (Powell et al., 2005; Brenner et al., 2011). Especially with the rapid pace of competition and the constant updates to technology, the formation and running of an innovation network is increasingly a result of conscious and organized behaviors of organizations focused on a common technology-innovation task (Podolny and Page, 1998; Cowan et al., 2007; Yang, 2020). Some of the latest studies show that power is very important or even dominant in R&D collaborations and networks (Back and Kohtamäki, 2015; Bujor and Avasilcăi, 2018; Hao and Feng, 2018; Papadonikolaki, 2018; Valdez, 2018). There are strong relationships among attraction, dependency, and power (Hald et al., 2009; Ramsay and Wagner, 2009; Jakobsen et al., 2019). Therefore, power can provide a new and unique perspective for solving the above research problems. In this sense, this paper introduces the term “knowledge power” into the study of technology-innovation networks and defines it as the inter-organizational power-dependence relation that is formed on the basis of organizational knowledge and is eventually manifested by organizational positions in a “power network.”1 It thus matches the multilevel feature of the innovation network and combines multiple research perspectives. Also, network actors’ active roles in the network are revealed well by the exertion of their power and the power interactions among them. However, questions such as how knowledge power comes into being, what factors shape it, and how to measure it remain challenging and unsolved. Therefore, this paper aims to (1) illustrate knowledge power’s formation path in innovation networks by synthesizing the relevant literature; (2) offer suggestions for how organizational knowledge characteristics impact it at different network levels; and (3) provide a multilevel measurement model for it, and test the propositions by mathematical inference.

Formation of Knowledge Power

Origin

In sociology, Foucault and Gordon (1980) takes knowledge as being always inextricably enmeshed in relations of power in that the base of power is knowledge and the use of power is to apply knowledge. Latiff and Hassan (2008) advance the term “knowledge power,” which is derived from the control of knowledge. In innovation networks, the origin of power from knowledge is most obvious. The aim of organizations in entering into technology-innovation alliances is to profit from the knowledge possessed by others (Cassiman and Veugelers, 2006; Jorge et al., 2021). They pool their knowledge and use it as an input into new knowledge production, and repeated alliance formation creates a network (Cowan et al., 2007). An organization’s knowledge characteristics, therefore, determine its attractiveness as a knowledge supplier in the network (Pérez-Nordtvedt et al., 2008; Pulles et al., 2014). Its bargaining power and indispensability are positively associated with its ability to retain control rights to intellectual assets (Leiponen, 2008), and differences in organizations’ knowledge characteristics predict the degree of power one unit has over another (Wong et al., 2008).

Power is not derived exclusively from knowledge. Power has its roots not only in the knowledge asymmetry among organizations but also in their differences in terms of capability (Conner, 1991; Enkel et al., 2017). The term “power” is derived from the Latin word potestas or potentia, meaning capability. Clegg (1989) states that power is a capability premised on resource control. In an innovation network, an organization’s technology-innovation capability is the most fundamental and important factor determining its influence (Li et al., 2020), and the most influential organization always has stronger capabilities for searching for and absorbing useful knowledge than others (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Prajogo et al., 2020).

The two concepts of capability and knowledge are often interconnected. On the one hand, organizational capabilities are seen as collective knowledge (Prahalad and Hamel, 1990) or as a property of knowledge (SubbaNarasimha, 2001). On the other hand, knowledge, as a resource, is thought to be one of the most important firm capabilities (Teece et al., 1997), and the level of knowledge of a firm describes its capacity to generate technological innovation (Wersching, 2007). Several terms related to both concepts appear frequently in the research literature, such as knowledge capabilities (Dawson, 2000; Ogulin et al., 2020), knowledge-based resource capabilities (Carrillo and Gaimon, 2004), knowledge activation (Tortoriello, 2008), knowledge integration capability (Xi et al., 2020), and dynamics of capability search and creation (Helfat, 2018). These indicate that knowledge and capability can embrace each other and coexist side by side and even within each other.

In an innovation network, organizational knowledge and capabilities should not be studied separately. Knowledge is the basis for capabilities (Grant, 1995). The more profound an organization’s knowledge, the stronger its capabilities. However, knowledge is an internal and relatively static resource. It can only be applied and used through organizational capabilities and then sensed and identified by outsiders. Knowledge power derives ultimately from organizational knowledge, which, however, may not be entirely or continuously in an active state. There is “sleeping knowledge” (Charue-Duboc et al., 2010), which is knowledge that is not being used effectively or of which the organization may even be unaware. Only after being activated by capabilities can an organization’s knowledge be applied and used in technology-innovation activities, embodied through technology-innovation processes and outcomes, and sensed and identified by other network actors. Those who need but do not have the knowledge will consequently be attracted to and develop a knowledge dependence on the organization (Howard et al., 2016). A positive net dependence generates knowledge power. Therefore, this paper proposes the term “activated knowledge” and defines it as knowledge that is not only owned by an organization but also activated by its capabilities so that it is ready to be used and identified. Activated knowledge is the direct origin of knowledge power.

Formation Path

An innovation network is a complicated form of network organization, and multilevel analyses are usually adopted in the study of such networks. A popular approach is to divide the network into three levels: the organization/firm/actor level, the inter-organizational level/dyad level/dyadic level, and the network level (Contractor et al., 2006; Provan et al., 2007). This approach considers individual organizations as the fundamental component of the network. Their micro-changes and interactions, such as cooperation and pairings, eventually result in the static structure and dynamic evolution of the macro network (Kong et al., 2019). Accordingly, this paper follows this approach and terms the three levels as the actor level, dyadic level, and network level.

Knowledge power is also multilevel in nature. Burt (1977) points out that when studying power, three general aspects must be distinguished: the bases of power (possession of resources), which are converted into manifestations of power (structure in influence relationships among decision-makers) via the processes of power. According to related studies (Emerson, 1962; Casciaro and Piskorski, 2005; Cho, 2020), power is a dependence relation, which in innovation networks means interdependence on one another’s knowledge. This interdependence is rooted in organizations’ heterogeneous capabilities and knowledge at the actor level and is eventually manifested as a knowledge-power network at the network level through interactions among inter-organizational relations at the dyadic level. Thus, by conducting a multilevel analysis, knowledge power can be better described as follows:

1. At the actor level: one actor alone cannot generate knowledge power, which is formed in a relational context, but organizational activated knowledge is knowledge power’s direct origin. An organization with activated knowledge favorable to the technology-innovation task will be highly attractive to other network actors. Its knowledge attractiveness leads to knowledge dependencies on the part of those who need its knowledge to accomplish the task, eventually giving rise to its knowledge power over them. Thus, at this level, knowledge power is conceptualized as knowledge attractiveness.

2. At the dyadic level: two actors’ mutual knowledge attractiveness forms an inter-organizational knowledge dependence relation. The differences in their activated knowledge result in a knowledge-dependence asymmetry that induces relative knowledge power (RKP). The party that has less unilateral knowledge dependence—and, consequently, positive RKP—is in a position of power advantage, whereas the other party is in a disadvantageous power position.

3. At the network level: multiple dyadic knowledge-power relations form a knowledge-power network, and an organization’s RKPs from various dyadic relations accumulate into a total knowledge power that is referred to as network knowledge power (NKP) in this paper. The magnitude of an organization’s NKP determines its position in the power network. Relative to most other network actors, those organizations that have bigger NKPs will occupy the central positions, and the one with the highest centrality will become the core organization, with a significant degree of influence over the whole network.

The formation path of knowledge power is shown in Figure 1.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1. The formation path of knowledge power.

The Determinants of Knowledge Power

Activated knowledge is the direct origin of knowledge power, so an organization’s activated knowledge characteristics (AKCs) determine whether its knowledge power, i.e., its knowledge attractiveness, is large or small; whether its position in a dyadic relation is power advantageous or power disadvantageous; and whether it is at the core or on the periphery of the power network. This section will analyze what these characteristics are and how they impact knowledge power.

Activated Knowledge Characteristics

Studies of the characteristics of knowledge propose various attributes such as knowledge depth, knowledge breadth, and knowledge similarity (Prabhu et al., 2005); knowledge value, knowledge rarity, knowledge inimitability, and knowledge non-substitutability (Pérez-Nordtvedt et al., 2008); and knowledge criticality, knowledge non-substitutability, and knowledge centricity (Wong et al., 2008). These studies provide the most popular and accepted characteristics of knowledge, but they neglect the possible interactions among these characteristics and do not take the multilevel nature of networks into consideration. This paper holds that a multilevel framework for AKCs should be built to perform a better investigation of how knowledge determines power in innovation networks.

1. At the actor level: AKCs should reflect the absolute level of an organization’s activated knowledge, with the purpose of measuring their impact on its knowledge attractiveness. In previous studies, factors such as knowledge depth and knowledge breadth are commonly used. Knowledge depth refers to the amount of within-field knowledge possessed by the organization, whereas knowledge breadth is the range of fields over which the organization has knowledge (Prabhu et al., 2005). These are the most fundamental knowledge characteristics and are used in this paper to measure the absolute level of an organization’s activated knowledge in its own context.

2. At the dyadic level: AKCs should reflect the relative level of an organization’s activated knowledge compared with another party, with the purpose of measuring how they determine its RKP. In previous studies, factors such as knowledge criticality, knowledge similarity, knowledge complementarity, and knowledge substitutability were commonly used. The first three all focus on the focal dyadic relation and are highly related. Knowledge similarity is in inverse proportion to knowledge complementarity within the knowledge portfolio required by the technology-innovation task. As network actors need heterogeneous knowledge or capabilities to cooperate (Pfeffer and Gerald, 1978; Wersching, 2007; Samarra and Biggiero, 2008), the less complementary (and the more similar) the focal organization’s knowledge is to that of the others, the lower the other perceives its knowledge criticality to be (Wong et al., 2008). Knowledge substitutability, however, involves the dyadic relations of the focal actor with third-network actors and measures the degree to which its knowledge can be replaced by them. It reflects the impact of other dyadic relations on the focal relation. In all, AKCs at the dyadic level are chosen as follows: knowledge complementarity that shows the degree to which one organization’s activated knowledge is complementary to the other party, and knowledge substitutability that reveals the degree to which one organization’s activated knowledge can be replaced by third parties.

3. At the network level: AKCs should reflect the relative level of an organization’s activated knowledge in the whole network, with the purpose of measuring how they determine its NKP. In previous studies, factors such as knowledge rarity, knowledge uniqueness, and knowledge centricity are commonly used. Knowledge rarity and knowledge uniqueness both show the relative level of an organization’s activated knowledge compared with the network’s average knowledge level. They are highly interrelated, as an organization’s knowledge should be unique and cannot be easily simulated by other network actors if it manages to keep its knowledge rare in the network. Also, when an organization’s knowledge is unique and difficult to copy, its knowledge rarity is usually high. Knowledge centrality shows the importance of an organization’s knowledge to the technology-innovation task. As an innovation network comes into being to accomplish the task, the more an organization’s activated knowledge meets the task’s requirements, the more important and central it is to the whole network. Therefore, AKCs at the network level are chosen as follows: knowledge rarity, i.e., the degree to which an organization’s knowledge is rare in the network, and knowledge centrality, i.e., the degree to which an organization’s knowledge is important for the technology-innovation task.

Concept Model

1. At the actor level: the concept of attraction comes from social psychology, where it is seen as a way of bringing parties together in a voluntary manner (Hare et al., 1959; Blau, 1964). Attraction is seen as having the potential to explain why business relationships commence and develop, which is relevant to dyadic business relationships (Mortensen, 2012) and connected to future motivation in relationships (Salo et al., 2009). As a kind of scarce resource, knowledge can generate attraction in the context of innovation. The depth and the breadth of an organization’s activated knowledge determine its potential knowledge attraction to other network actors. A profound activated knowledge depth indicates that an organization has significant activated knowledge within a field, so it may have more attractiveness to other network actors that need the knowledge to achieve the technology-innovation goal. A wide activated knowledge breadth means that a wide range of fields are covered by an organization’s activated knowledge, meaning that there are more possibilities for it to attract other network actors. Knowledge attraction gives the other companies motivation to start a relationship with the owner and maintain it in the future. Therefore

Proposition 1

The more profound the focal organization’s activated knowledge depth is, the more potential knowledge attractiveness it has to other network actors.

Proposition 2

The wider the focal organization’s activated knowledge breadth is, the more potential knowledge attractiveness it has to other network actors.

2. At the dyadic level: studies in the field of psychology have found that as relative ability declines, the party that originally held more power will give up some power (Lindell and Campione-Barr, 2017). In other words, the shifting of capability will change the balance of inter-organizational power. Activated knowledge is defined in this paper as a result of capability and can generate and change relative power between two parties. Those with expertise can gain access to more alternatives; at the same time, this increases the certainty of access to alternative options, so they feel more empowered (Rlp et al., 2019), and they do have more power in negotiation and other aspects (Elfenbein, 2015; Wright et al., 2016; Schaerer et al., 2020). The emergence of greater psychological and behavioral power is closely related to attraction and dependence (Hald et al., 2009; Ramsay and Wagner, 2009). The larger the knowledge attractiveness an organization has for other network players, the more it is possible for the organization to be depended on and to acquire positive RKP. From potential knowledge attractiveness to effective RKP, however, there are two conditions: the other party must demand the activated knowledge that the focal actor has, and it must be difficult for it to acquire the knowledge from somewhere else. These conditions are indeed implied in AKCs at the dyadic level. Gaining complementary resources is an important inducement for organizations to enter into cooperation, as complementary resources will increase the interdependence between organizations (Pfeffer and Gerald, 1978). Thus, when an organization has a high level of activated knowledge that is complementary to the other party’s knowledge, this leads to the dependence of the latter on the former, which increases the possibility for an asymmetric dependence and consequent RKP to exist. However, if the focal organization’s activated knowledge can be easily substituted for by a third-network actor, the other party’s dependence will be distributed, which reduces the focal organization’s RKP. Therefore

Proposition 3

In a dyadic relation, the more the focal organization’s activated knowledge is complementary to the other party’s knowledge, the more RKP it has over the other party.

Proposition 4

In a dyadic relation, the more the focal organization’s activated knowledge can be substituted for by a third-network actor, the less RKP it has over the other party.

3. At the network level: power can be generated by social status. First, people with high social status enjoy respect and appreciation, resulting in others voluntarily giving them preferential treatment (Ball and Eckel, 1996). Second, people with high social status enjoy more social capital, e.g., in terms of being able to reach a wider range of negotiable objects. In order to obtain more social capital through them, other people will also give them power (Kim and Fragale, 2005). In an innovation network, companies with numerous power advantages have such a high social status and, thus, have absolute power. When an organization can acquire positive knowledge power from various dyadic relations with most network players, it will accumulate considerable NKP. This accumulating effect is ultimately demonstrated by the impacts of its AKCs on its NKP. The rarer an organization’s activated knowledge is in the whole network and the more important its knowledge is to the technology-innovation task, the more likely it is that the organization enjoys overall knowledge advantages over the other network actors. There is, therefore, a large probability of it acquiring positive RKPs and consequently considerable NKP and of occupying a central position with high social status in the knowledge-power network. Therefore,

Proposition 5

In the network, the more the focal organization’s activated knowledge rarity is, the more NKP it has.

Proposition 6

In the network, the more the focal organization’s activated knowledge centrality is, the more NKP it has.

The overall concept model is shown in Figure 2.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 2. The concept model of AKCs’ impact on knowledge power.

Measurement Model

Based on the above analyses and taking the inter-organizational dependence equation proposed by Dastmalchian (1986) as groundwork, this section builds a multilevel measurement model for knowledge power and tests the above propositions by mathematical inference. The model incorporates the following assumptions:

Assumption 1: In an innovation network, inter-organizational collaborations are formed to accomplish a given technology-innovation task that requires a knowledge portfolio set as K0=k01,k02,,k0n, with n for the breadth of the knowledge required and k0r for the depth of knowledge r needed to fulfill the task. For the sake of simplicity, the importance of different items of knowledge to the technology-innovation task is ignored by setting the weight of each item of knowledge’s importance as 1.

Assumption 2: In the network, there are m organizations, and they know the other actors’ activated knowledge structure very well. That is because: (1) as defined above, activated knowledge refers to knowledge that is activated by organizational capabilities, embodied through technology-innovation activities or outcomes, and able to be sensed and identified by outsiders; (2) organizations in the same innovation network are usually located in one industry or homogeneous zones and interact frequently, which increases their number of mutual acquaintances; and (3) when an organization cannot achieve a technology-innovation goal by itself, it will be willing to let its potential partners know its knowledge advantages, with the aim of attracting them to cooperate. Thus, this assumption is reasonable.

At the Actor Level

In an innovation network, power is derived from organizational knowledge, as mentioned above, and organizational activated knowledge is the precondition for knowledge power. Set Ki=ki1,ki2,,kin, with kir for the depth of organization i’s knowledge r. Ki reflects organization i’s activated knowledge depth and breadth in terms of the technology-innovation task, i.e., its activated knowledge.

Set

Yi=yi1,yi2,yin,yir=1,kirk0r0,kir<k0r,r1,n    (1)

yir indicates whether organization i is qualified in knowledge r according to K0, with 0 for no and 1 for yes. Thus, Yi represents the degree to which organization i can meet the technology-innovation goal. Consequently, 1yi1,1yi2,,1yin reflects the set of knowledge that organization i needs to acquire from cooperation. The more chances i has to achieve the goal, the more attractive it is to other network actors for knowledge cooperation, and the more critical it is to the whole network. As Yi is directly impacted by Ki, i’s potential knowledge attractiveness is in direct proportion to i’s activated knowledge depth and breadth. Proposition 1 and Proposition 2 are met.

At the Dyadic Level

At this level, knowledge power is manifested as the RKP caused by asymmetric knowledge dependencies between organizations. Dastmalchian (1986) proposes the equation Dependence=Essentiality*1/Substitutability, with substitutability determined by the number of sources of resources available. The essentiality of organization i’s knowledge r to organization j relies on the following factors: if organization i’s activated knowledge r meets the technology-innovation requirement (yir), if organization j needs to acquire knowledge r from outside (1–yjr), and the degree to which organization j depends on organization i’s activated knowledge r (kir – kir). Suppose the dependence of organization j on organization i is dji:

dji=,rnyir1yjrkirkjr1imyir,r1n    (2)

Inter-organizational relative power is measured by the difference between their dependencies on each other (Pfeffer, 1981; Kumar et al., 1995). Let pij be i’s RKP over j, and we get

pij=djidij    (3)

By substituting Equation (2) into Equation (3), we get

pij=,rnkirkjryir+yjr2yiryjr1imyir,r1n    (4)

Set

Cij=ki1kj1yi1+yj12yi1yj1,ki2kj2yi2+yj22yi2yj2,,kinkjnyin+yjn2yinyjn    (5)

(yir +yjr – 2yiryjr) is the residual part of the union of i and j’s activated knowledge sets after subtracting their intersection, i.e., the degree to which i and j’s activated knowledge are complementary in terms of knowledge breadth; (kir–kjr) represents the degree to which i’s activated knowledge r is complementary to j’s in terms of knowledge depth. Therefore, Cij is indeed i’s activated knowledge complementarity to j’s.

Set

NS=ns1,ns2,,nsn,nsr=1imyir,imyir0M,imyir=0,r1n,Misanonzeroconstant    (6)

imyiris the total number of organizations that are qualified in knowledge r according to K0, and represents the substitutability of knowledge r (Dastmalchian, 1986). Further, nsr, as its reciprocal, refers to knowledge r’s non-substitutability. When imyir=0, the value of yir+yjr2yiryjr must be zero, so the exact value of M has no impact on the result.

By substituting Equations (5)Equations (6) into Equation (4), we get

pij=CijTNS    (7)

Therefore, organization i’s RKP over j is directly proportional to i’s activated knowledge complementarity to j’s, and is in inverse proportion to its activated knowledge substitutability (in direct proportion to its activated knowledge non-substitutability). Proposition 3 and Proposition 4 are met.

At the Network Level

At this level, knowledge power is manifested as the accumulation of an organization’s RKPs in the knowledge-power network, i.e., its NKP. Let pi be organization i’s NKP, and we get

pi=jmpij    (8)

By substituting Equation (4) into Equation (8), we get

pi=jmpij=jmrnkirkjryir+yjr2yiryjrusr,r1,n    (9)

To simplify the mathematical inference and to highlight the major determining factors, this paper substitutes (kir–kjr) for (yir–yjr) in Equation (9) with the following justification: although NKP is derived from the accumulation of RKPs, as demonstrated in Equation (8), in reality, it is ultimately embodied by the organization’s position in the knowledge-power network. Indicators of network position such as centrality are often used to measure network power (Cook, 1977; Brass and Burkhardt, 1992; Ibarra, 1993; Mehra et al., 2006), and the nature of RKPs, as being positive or negative, has a much more significant influence on an organization’s network position than their magnitude. To a knowledge demander that has a certain degree of activated knowledge but that is inadequate to the technology-innovation goal, for example, although its existing knowledge may reduce its dependence on other qualified organizations, the fact cannot be changed that it still needs to depend on others for the technology-innovation task. Therefore, it will initiate collaborations with knowledge suppliers and try to maintain cooperative relations with them. This will increase the knowledge suppliers’ indegree centrality, which is a major index of a network actor’s power. The value of (yir–yjr) reveals the nature of i’s RKP over j on knowledge r, as being at a power-advantageous (positive value), disadvantageous (negative value), or balanced (zero) position, and determines whether an organization is a knowledge demander or a knowledge supplier. So, although (kir–kjr) can imply more about the NKP’s quantity, most of the information that it contains can be explained by (yir–yjr). Therefore, by substituting (kir–kjr) for (yir–yjr) in Equation (9), we get

pi=rnpir=rnmyirjmyjr1=rnyirmjmyjrn,r1,n    (10)

Set

S=s1,s2,,sn,sr=mimyir=1jmyjrm,imyir0N,imyir=0,r1,nandNisanonzeroconstant    (11)

The fraction jmyjrm, with the denominator being the total number of organizations in the network and the numerator being the total number of qualified organizations in knowledge r, represents the density of the organizations with qualified knowledge r in the network. Further, S, as its reciprocal, reflects the rarity of knowledge r in the network.

By substituting Equation (11) into Equation (10), we get

pi=YiTSnr1,n    (12)

As n is a constant, the value of pi is determined by Yi and S. Yi represents whether an organization i’s various types of knowledge are qualified for the technology-innovation task and measures its knowledge centrality in the network. S represents knowledge rarity, as analyzed above. Therefore, organization i’s NKP is determined by i’s activated knowledge centrality as well as its activated knowledge rarity. Proposition 5 and Proposition 6 are met.

Conclusion

Findings

The KBV is a major perspective for studying innovation networks, as it captures nicely the feature of technology-innovation networks that knowledge is the key resource. Relying exclusively on the KBV, however, overlooks both the multilevel structure of the network and network actors’ active role and can hardly reveal how the network, as a spontaneous system, evolves into a macro structure through interactions among the actors through micro activities. To provide a solution to these problems, the concept of knowledge power is introduced here, based on related theories. This paper suggests that knowledge power reflects the nature of inter-organizational relations in networks, fits their multilevel character, and matches the latest findings that inter-organizational power relations are asymmetric and that innovation networks are hierarchical. Studies of knowledge power can provide a novel clue for research on the static structure as well as the dynamic evolution of innovation networks. Grounded in the above reasons, this paper initiates some basic analyses of knowledge power as follows:

1. Knowledge power’s origins in knowledge and capability are analyzed, and by combining the multilevel feature of the innovation network, knowledge power’s formation path is described;

2. The concept of activated knowledge, which is thought to be the major determinant of knowledge power, is proposed; a multilevel framework for activated knowledge’s characteristics is built; and their impacts on knowledge power are analyzed; and

3. Measurement equations for knowledge power at different levels are deduced by taking a well-accepted dependence equation as the groundwork; the above propositions are tested; and a multilevel measurement model for knowledge power is established.

The major work of this paper is shown in Figure 3.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 3. Knowledge power in the innovation network.

Research Limitations/Implications

The concept of knowledge power inherits the well-accepted feature of technology-innovation networks that knowledge is the most important element and captures the newly revealed phenomenon that power relations in the network are asymmetric. This is a long-overlooked research topic in technology-innovation-network studies that has received little systemic investigation. This paper analyzes knowledge power’s formation path, proposes propositions for its determining factors, and builds a measurement model. However, as a fundamental analysis of an almost entirely new concept, this paper has some deficiencies; to address them, future research can be conducted in the following areas:

1. Empirical studies can be conducted to test AKCs’ impacts on knowledge power on multiple levels to validate the propositions proposed by this paper with practical data.

2. Based on the static measurement model of knowledge power, a dynamic model may be developed to simulate knowledge power’s formation and changes and to provide a groundwork for further studies of network evaluation.

3. Based on inter-organizational resource dependence theory, this paper combines the KBV and the dynamic capability theory to explore the formation mechanism from knowledge to power. However, the relational view derived from the sociology field is also an important perspective for studying inter-organizational relationships and proposes some important variables such as trust, reciprocity, communication, etc. Future research may explore the interactions between these variables and knowledge power to arrive at a better understanding of inter-organizational relationships in innovation networks.

Practical Implications

The members of an open innovation network are loosely coupled, and the interactions among the members form a dynamic network. Such interactions are greatly impacted by members’ visibility and authority in the network, the availability of network resources, and the dynamics of the overall goals of the network. Power is a key factor interwoven with these issues, especially in innovation networks, which usually have some core actors. Gaining a better understanding of the structure and determinants of knowledge power is crucial to the success of network members. The analysis and outcomes of this paper may:

1. Inspire a power-disadvantaged network actor to actively improve its influence and importance in the network and to change its position, both in dyadic rations and in the overall network, by improving its own knowledge and capabilities;

2. Remind a power-advantaged network actor to apply its RKP and NKP reasonably to spur a next-stage technology-innovation task in favor of its own AKCs, so as to anchor its power-advantageous position; and

3. Make it easier to identify network actors’ power by distinguishing their AKCs, as proposed in this paper, and to maintain an overall coordinated and sustainable network development by emphasizing the active roles of network actors, especially those with a great degree of power.

Author Contributions

SC: ideas, formulation of the research goals, design of methodology, creation of models, verification of the research outputs, investigation of the outcomes, application of mathematical techniques to analyse, creations of the original draft preparation, management for the research activity planning, execution and revision, and acquisition of the financial support for the projects. ZF: coordination for the revision process and review and editing the revised manuscript before it were formally edited by the professional proofreading servicer. ZP: search, analysis, and interpretation of related and up-to-date references and pre-formatting the references list before the manuscript was formally edited by the professional proofreading servicer. SQ: search, analysis, and interpretation of related and up-to-date references and pre-formatting the references list before the manuscript was formally edited by the professional proofreading servicer.

Funding

This research was funded by the Key Research Institute of Philosophy and Social Science of the Education Department of Shaanxi Provincial Government (No. 18JZ010), Research Project on Major Theoretical and Practical Problems of Philosophy and Social Sciences in Shaanxi Province (No. 2021Nd0029), Xi’an Social Science Planning Fund Project (No. Gl51), and Science and Technology Innovation Team of Innovative Talent Promotion Plan in Shaanxi Province (No. 2021TD-35).

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Footnotes

1. ^The term “power network” was coined by Emerson (1962) and refers to two or more connected power-dependence relations.

References

An, W., Huang, Q., Liu, H., and Wu, J. (2021). The match between business model design and knowledge base in firm growth: from a knowledge-based view. Tech. Anal. Strat. Manag. doi: 10.1080/09537325.2021.1890011

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Back, I., and Kohtamäki, M. (2015). Boundaries of R&D collaboration. Technovation 45-46, 15–28. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2015.07.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ball, S. B., and Eckel, C. C. (1996). Buying status: experimental evidence on status in negotiation. Psychol. Market. 13, 381–405. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1520-6793(199607)13:4<379::AID-MAR4>3.0.CO;2-7

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Blau, P. M. (ed.) (1964). Exchange and Power in Social Life. London: John Wiley.

Google Scholar

Brass, D. J., and Burkhardt, M. E. (1992). “Centrality and power in organizations,” in Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action. eds. N. Nohria and R. Eccles (Boston: Harvard Business School Press), 191–215.

Google Scholar

Brenner, T., Cantner, U., and Graf, H. (2011). Innovation networks: measurement, performance and regional dimensions. Ind. Innov. 18, 1–5. doi: 10.1080/13662716.2010.528925

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bujor, A., and Avasilcăi, S. (2018). Open innovation in creattive industries. Part I: innovation and design. IOP Conf. Ser.: Mater. Sci. Eng. 400:062007. doi: 10.1088/1757-899X/400/6/062007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Burt, R. S. (1977). Power in a social topology. Soc. Sci. Res. 6, 1–83. doi: 10.1016/0049-089X(77)90001-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Carrillo, J. E., and Gaimon, C. (2004). Managing knowledge-based resource capabilities under uncertainty. Manag. Sci. 50, 1504–1518. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1040.0234

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Casciaro, T., and Piskorski, M. J. (2005). Power imbalance, mutual dependence, and constraint absorption: a closer look at resource dependence theory. Admin. Sci. Quart. 50, 167–199. doi: 10.2189/asqu.2005.50.2.167

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cassiman, B., and Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Manag. Sci. 52, 68–82. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Charue-Duboc, F., Aggeri, F., Chanal, V., and Garel, G. (2010). “Managing Exploratory Innovation.” in Paper presented at the European Academy of Management Conference ; May 19–22, 2010; Roma, Italy.

Google Scholar

Cho, Y. (2020). The effects of knowledge assets and path dependence in innovations on firm value in the Korean semiconductor industry. Sustainability 12:2319. doi: 10.3390/su12062319

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Clegg, S. (1989). Radical revisions: power, discipline and organizations. Organ. Stud. 10, 97–115. doi: 10.1177/017084068901000106

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cohen, W. M., and Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on leaning and innovation. Admin. Sci. Quart. 35, 128–152. doi: 10.2307/2393553

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Conner, K. R. (1991). A historical comparison of resource-based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organizations economics: do we have a new theory of the firm? J. Manage. 17, 121–154. doi: 10.1177/014920639101700109

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Contractor, N. S., Wasserman, S., and Faust, K. (2006). Testing multitheoretical, multilevel hypotheses about organizational networks: an analytic framework and empirical example. Acad. Manag. Rev. 31, 681–703. doi: 10.5465/amr.2006.21318925

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cook, K. S. (1977). Exchange and power in networks of interorganizational relations. Sociol. Quart. 18, 62–82. doi: 10.1111/j.1533-8525.1977.tb02162.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cowan, R., and Jonard, N. (2009). Knowledge portfolios and the organization of innovation networks. Acad. Manag. Rev. 34, 320–342. doi: 10.5465/amr.2008.0052

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cowan, R., Jonard, N., and Zimmermann, J. B. (2007). Bilateral collaboration and the emergence of networks. Manag. Sci. 53, 1051–1067. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0618

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dantas, E., and Bell, M. (2009). Latecomer firms and the emergence and development of knowledge networks: the case of Petrobras in Brazil. Res. Policy 38, 829–844. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2009.01.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dastmalchian, A. (1986). Organizational resource dependencies and goal orientation. J. Bus. Res. 14, 387–402. doi: 10.1016/0148-2963(86)90036-6

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dawson, R. (2000). Knowledge capabilities as the focus of organisational development and strategy. J. Knowl. Manag. 4, 320–327. doi: 10.1108/13673270010379876

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dhanaraj, C., and Parkhe, A. (2006). Orchestrating innovation networks. Acad. Manag. Rev. 31, 659–669. doi: 10.5465/amr.2006.21318923

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Eisenhardt, K. M., and Martin, J. A. (2000). Dynamic capabilities: what are they? Strateg. Manage. J. 21, 1105–1121. doi: 10.1002/1097-0266(200010/11)21:10/11<1105::AID-SMJ133>3.0.CO;2-E

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Elfenbein, H. A. (2015). Individual differences in negotiation: a nearly abandoned pursuit revived. Curr. Dir. Psychol. Sci. 24, 131–136. doi: 10.1177/0963721414558114

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Emerson, R. M. (1962). Power-dependence relations. Am. Sociol. Rev. 27, 31–41. doi: 10.2307/2089716

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Enkel, E., Heil, S., Hengstler, M., and Wirth, H. (2017). Exploratory and exploitative innovation: to what extent do the dimensions of individual level absorptive capacity contribute? Technovation 60–61, 29–38. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2016.08.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ferreira, J., Coelho, A., and Moutinho, L. (2020). Dynamic capabilities, creativity and innovation capability and their impact on competitive advantage and firm performance: the moderating role of entrepreneurial orientation. Technovation 92-93, 102061–102093. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2018.11.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Foucault, M., and Gordon, C. (1980). Power/Knowledge: Selected Interviews and Other Writings. New York: Pantheon Books, 1972–1977.

Google Scholar

Gilsing, V., Lemmens, C., and Duysters, G. (2007). Strategic alliance networks and innovation: a deterministic and voluntaristic view combined. Technol. Anal. Strateg. 19, 227–249. doi: 10.1080/09537320601168151

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Grant, R. A. (1995). A knowledge-based theory of inter-firm collaboration. Acad. Manag. Ann. 1995, 17–21. doi: 10.5465/ambpp.1995.17536229

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hald, K. S., Cordon, C., and Vollmann, T. E. (2009). Towards an understanding of attraction in buyer–supplier relationships. Ind. Market. Manag. 38, 960–970. doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2008.04.015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hao, B., and Feng, Y. (2018). Leveraging learning forces in asymmetric alliances: small firms’ perceived power imbalance in driving exploration and exploitation. Technovation 78, 27–39. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2018.07.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hare, A. P., Thibaut, J. W., and Kelley, H. H. (1959). The social psychology of groups. Soc. Serv. Rev. 1, 184–186.

Google Scholar

Heiman, B. A., and Nickerson, J. A. (2004). Empirical evidence regarding the tension between knowledge sharing and knowledge expropriation in collaborations. Manage. Decis. Econ. 25, 401–420. doi: 10.1002/mde.1198

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Helfat, C. E. (2018). The dynamics of capability search and creation. Ind. Corp. Change 27, 1155–1157. doi: 10.1093/icc/dty044

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Howard, M., Withers, M., and Tihanyi, L. (2016). Knowledge dependence and the formation of director interlocks. Acad. Manag. J. 60, 1986–2013. doi: 10.5465/amj.2015.0499

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ibarra, H. (1993). Network centrality, power, and innovation involvement: determinants of technical and administrative roles. Acad. Manag. J. 36, 471–501.

Google Scholar

Ireland, R. D., Hitt, M. A., and Vaidyanath, D. (2002). Alliance management as a source of competitive advantage. J. Manage. 28, 413–446. doi: 10.1177/014920630202800308

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jakobsen, S., Lauvås, T. A., and Steinmo, M. (2019). Collaborative dynamics in environmental R&D alliances. J. Clean. Prod. 212, 950–959. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.285

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jha, P. P., and Cottam, E. (2021). Embeddedness of inter-firm ties and knowledge creation. Eur. Manag. Rev. (early view). doi: 10.1111/emre.12455

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jordão, R. V. D. (2015). Knowledge and information management practices in small and medium-sized enterprises organized in cooperative networks: a multi case comparative study in the Brazilian industry. Int. J. Cancer 76, 865–871. doi: 10.1590/1981-5344/1737

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jorge, F., Arnaldo, C., and Luiz, M. (2021). The influence of strategic alliances on innovation and new product development through the effects of exploration and exploitation. Manage. Decis. 59, 524–567. doi: 10.1108/MD-09-2019-1239

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kim, T. (2015). Inter-organizational knowledge transfer through corporate venture capital investment. Manage. Decis. 53, 1601–1618. doi: 10.1108/MD-12-2014-0668

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kim, P. H., and Fragale, A. R. (2005). Choosing the path to bargaining power: an empirical comparison of BATNAs and contributions in negotiation. J. Appl. Psychol. 90, 373–381. doi: 10.1037/0021-9010.90.2.373

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kong, X., Xu, Q., and Zhu, T. (2019). Dynamic evolution of knowledge sharing behavior among enterprises in the cluster innovation network based on evolutionary game theory. Sustainability 12:75. doi: 10.3390/su12010075

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kumar, N., Sheer, L. K., and Steenkamp, J. E. M. (1995). The effects of perceived interdependence on dealer attitudes. J. Marketing Res. 32, 348–356. doi: 10.1177/002224379503200309

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lai, J., Lui, S. S., and Tsang, E. W. K. (2016). Intrafirm knowledge transfer and employee innovative behavior: the role of total and balanced knowledge flows. J. Prod. Innovat. Manag. 33, 90–103. doi: 10.1111/jpim.12262

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Latiff, H. S., and Hassan, A. (2008). Rise and fall of knowledge power: an in-depth investigation. Humanomics 24, 17–27. doi: 10.1108/08288660810851441

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Leiponen, A. (2008). Control of intellectual assets in client relationships: implications for innovation. Strateg. Manage. J. 29, 1371–1394. doi: 10.1002/smj.715

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, M., Zhang, J., Ramanathan, R., and Li, R. (2020). Opening the black box: the impacts of environmental regulations on technological innovation. Int. J. Env. Res. Pub. He. 17:4365. doi: 10.3390/ijerph17124365

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lindell, A. K., and Campione-Barr, N. (2017). Relative power in sibling relationships across adolescence. New Dir. Child Adoles. 2017, 49–66. doi: 10.1002/cad.20201

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, L., Bo, Y., and Wu, W. (2019). The formation and effects of exploitative dynamic capabilities and explorative dynamic capabilities: an empirical study. Sustainability 11:2581. doi: 10.3390/su11092581

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lyu, C., Yang, J., Zhang, F., Teo, T. S. H., and Tian, M. (2020). How do knowledge characteristics affect firm’s knowledge sharing intention in interfirm cooperation? An empirical study. J. Bus. Res. 115, 48–60. doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.04.045

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Marjolein, C. J., and Caniëls, A. R. (2009). Power and dependence perspectives on outsourcing decisions. Eur. Manag. J. 27, 402–417. doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2009.01.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Matheus, T., Saunders, M., and Chakraborty, S. (2017). Multiple dimensions of power influencing knowledge integration in supply chains. R&D Manag. 47, 673–688. doi: 10.1111/radm.12243

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Matinheikki, J., Pesonen, T., Artto, K., and Peltokorpi, A. (2017). New value creation in business networks: the role of collective action in constructing system-level goals. Ind. Market. Manag. 67, 122–133. doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.06.011

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mehra, A., Dixon, A., Brass, D., and Robertson, B. (2006). The social network ties of group leaders: implications for group performance and leader reputation. Organ. Sci. 17, 64–79. doi: 10.1287/orsc.1050.0158

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mortensen, M. H. (2012). Understanding attractiveness in business relationships — a complete literature review. Ind. Market. Manag. 41, 1206–1218. doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2012.10.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mousavi, S., Bossink, B., and van Vliet, M. (2018). Dynamic capabilities and organizational routines for managing innovation towards sustainability. J. Clean. Prod. 203, 224–239. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.08.215

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mu, J. F. (2017). Dynamic capability and firm performance: the role of marketing capability and operations capability. IEEE T. Eng. Manage. 64, 554–565. doi: 10.1109/TEM.2017.2712099

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Na, C., Lee, D., Hwang, J., and Lee, C. (2020). Strategic groups emerged by selecting R&D collaboration partners and firms’ efficiency. Asian J. Technol. Inno. 29, 109–133. doi: 10.1080/19761597.2020.1788957

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ogulin, R., Guzman, G., and Nuwangi, S. M. (2020). Knowledge capabilities in supply chain networks: a taxonomy. J. Knowl. Manag. 24, 655–674. doi: 10.1108/JKM-06-2019-0266

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Oliver, C. (1991). Strategic responses to institutional processes. Acad. Manag. Rev. 16, 145–179. doi: 10.5465/amr.1991.4279002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Orton, J. D., and Weick, K. E. (1990). Loosely coupled systems: a reconceptualization. Acad. Manag. Rev. 15, 203–223. doi: 10.5465/amr.1990.4308154

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ouakouak, M. L., AlBuloushi, N., Ouedraogo, N., and Sawalha, N. (2021). Knowledge sharing as a give-and-take practice: the role of the knowledge receiver in the knowledge-sharing process. J. Knowl. Manag. doi: 10.1108/JKM-04-2020-0323 [Epub ahead of print]

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Papadonikolaki, E. (2018). Loosely coupled systems of innovation: aligning BIM adoption with implementation in Dutch construction. J. Manag. Eng. 34:6. doi: 10.1061/(ASCE)ME.1943-5479.0000644

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pérez-Nordtvedt, L., Kedia, B. L., Datta, D. K., and Rasheed, A. A. (2008). Effectiveness and efficiency of cross-border knowledge transfer: an empirical examination. J. Manage. Stud. 45, 714–744. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2008.00767.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pfeffer, J. (1981). Power in Organizations. Boston, MA: Pitman Publishing.

Google Scholar

Pfeffer, J., and Gerald, R. S. (1978). “The external control of organizations: a resource dependence perspective,” in Advances in International Marketing: Industrial Networks. eds. S. T. Cavusgil and D. D. Sharma (London: Jai Press Inc.), 289–302.

Google Scholar

Podolny, J., and Page, K. (1998). Network forms of organization. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 24, 57–76. doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.57

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Powell, W. W., White, D. R., Koput, K. W., and Owen-Smith, J. (2005). Network dynamics and field evolution: the growth of interorganizational collaboration in the life sciences. Am. J. Sociol. 110, 1132–1205. doi: 10.1086/421508

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Prabhu, J. C., Chandy, R. K., and Ellis, M. E. (2005). The impact of acquisitions on innovation: poison pill, placebo, or tonic. J. Marketing 69, 114–130. doi: 10.1509/jmkg.69.1.114.55514

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Prahalad, C. K., and Hamel, G. (1990). The core competence of the corporation. Harvard Bus. Rev. 68, 79–91.

Google Scholar

Prajogo, D., Chowdhury, M., Nair, A., and Cheng, T. (2020). Mitigating the performance implications of buyer’s dependence on supplier: the role of absorptive capacity and long-term relationship. Supply Chain Manag. 25, 693–707. doi: 10.1108/SCM-07-2019-0254

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Prester, J., Hernaus, T., Aleksić, A., and Trkman, P. (2019). “Performance effects of dynamic capabilities: the interaction effect of process management capabilities,” in Business Process Management: Blockchain and Central and Eastern Europe Forum. eds. C. DiCiccio, R. Gabryelczyk, L. GarciaBanuelos, T. Hernaus, R. Hull, and M. I. Stembergeret al. (Cham: Springer), 264–279.

Google Scholar

Provan, K. G., Fish, A., and Sydow, J. (2007). Interorganizational networks at the network level: a review of the empirical literature on whole networks. J. Manage. 33, 479–516. doi: 10.1177/0149206307302554

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pulles, N. J., Veldman, J., Schiele, H., and Sierksma, H. (2014). Pressure or pamper? The effects of power and trust dimensions on supplier resource allocation. J. Supply Chain Manag. 50, 16–36. doi: 10.1111/jscm.12049

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Quintane, E., Casselman, R. M., Reiche, B. S., and Nylund, P. A. (2011). Innovation as a knowledge-based outcome. J. Knowl. Manag. 15, 928–947. doi: 10.1108/13673271111179299

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ramsay, J., and Wagner, B. A. (2009). Organizational supplying behaviour: understanding supplier needs, wants and preferences. J. Purch. Supply Manag. 15, 127–138. doi: 10.1016/j.pursup.2009.02.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Rlp, A., Dec, B., Jes, C., Djs, D., Dv, A., and Mk, A. (2019). The power of phantom alternatives in negotiation: how what could be haunts what is. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 151, 34–48. doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2018.12.008

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Salo, A., Taehtinen, J., and Ulkuniemi, P. (2009). Twists and turns of triadic business relationship recovery. Ind. Market. Manag. 38, 618–632. doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2009.05.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Samarra, A., and Biggiero, L. (2008). Heterogeneity and specificity of inter-firm knowledge flows in innovation networks. J. Manage. Stud. 45, 800–828. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2008.00770.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Santoro, G., Thrassou, A., Bresciani, S., and Del Giudice, M. (2021). Do knowledge management and dynamic capabilities affect ambidextrous entrepreneurial intensity and firms’ performance? IEEE T. Eng. Manage. 68, 378–386. doi: 10.1109/TEM.2019.2907874

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Schaerer, M., Teo, L., Madan, N., and Swaab, R. I. (2020). Power and negotiation: review of current evidence and future directions. Curr. Opin. Psychol. 33, 47–51. doi: 10.1016/j.copsyc.2019.06.013

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Su, Y., Jiang, X., and Lin, Z. (2021). Simulation and relationship strength: characteristics of knowledge flows among subjects in a regional innovation system. Sci. Technol. Soc. doi: 10.1177/09717218211020476

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

SubbaNarasimha, P. N. (2001). Strategy in turbulent environments: the role of dynamic competence. Manage. Decis. Econ. 22, 201–212. doi: 10.1002/mde.1017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., and Shuen, A. (1997). Firm capabilities, resources, and the concept of strategy. Strategic Management Review 18, 509–533. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199708)18:7<509::AID-SMJ882>3.0.CO;2-Z

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Torres, R., Sidorova, A., and Jones, M. C. (2018). Enabling firm performance through business intelligence and analytics: a dynamic capabilities perspective. Inf. Manag. 55, 822–839. doi: 10.1016/j.im.2018.03.010

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tortoriello, M. (2008). Getting the most out of your network: social structure, formal boundaries and knowledge activation. Acad. Manage. PRO 2008, 1–6. doi: 10.5465/ambpp.2008.33645063

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Valdez, A. C. (2018). The diversity of why: a meta-analytical study of usage motivation in enterprise social networks. Univ. Access Inf. Soc. 17, 549–566. doi: 10.1007/s10209-017-0561-9

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wersching, K. (2007). Agglomeration in an innovative and differentiated industry with heterogeneous knowledge spillovers. J. Econ. Interact. Coor. 2, 1–25. doi: 10.1007/s11403-006-0010-y

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wong, S. S., Ho, V. T., and Lee, C. H. (2008). A power perspective to interunit knowledge transfer: linking knowledge attributes to unit power and the transfer of knowledge. J. Manage. 34, 127–150. doi: 10.1177/0149206307308912

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wright, G. D., Andersson, K. P., Gibson, C. C., and Evans, T. P. (2016). Decentralization can help reduce deforestation when user groups engage with local government. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A. 113, 14958–14963. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1610650114

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xi, Y., Wang, X., and Zhu, Y. (2020). Organizational unlearning and knowledge transfer in cross-border M&As: the mediating role of knowledge integration from a routine-based view. J. Knowl. Manag. 24, 841–860. doi: 10.1108/JKM-08-2019-0419

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yang, X. (2020). Coopetition for innovation in R&D consortia: moderating roles of size disparity and formal interaction. Asia Pac. J. Manag. doi: 10.1007/s10490-020-09733-x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yeow, A., Soh, C., and Hansen, R. (2018). Aligning with new digital strategy: a dynamic capabilities approach. J. Strategic Inf. Syst. 27, 43–58. doi: 10.1016/j.jsis.2017.09.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: knowledge power, inter-organizational power relation, knowledge-based view, innovation network, activated knowledge, power perception

Citation: Shi C, Zhang F, Zhu P and Shi Q (2021) How Is Knowledge Perceived as Power? A Multilevel Model of Knowledge Power in Innovation Networks. Front. Psychol. 12:630762. doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2021.630762

Received: 19 November 2020; Accepted: 27 August 2021;
Published: 20 October 2021.

Edited by:

Fabrizio Gerli, Ca’ Foscari University of Venice, Italy

Reviewed by:

Xie Yongping, Xidian University, China
Ji Yingdong, Shanxi University of Finance and Economics, China

Copyright © 2021 Shi, Zhang, Zhu and Shi. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Chengqi Shi, 40778428@qq.com

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.