Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Environ. Sci., 26 October 2021
Sec. Interdisciplinary Climate Studies

Socio-Economic Analysis of Climate Services in Disaster Risk Reduction: A Perspective on Pacific SIDS

David Newth
David Newth1*Geoff GooleyGeoff Gooley2Don GunasekeraDon Gunasekera3
  • 1CSIRO Climate Science Centre, Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organization, Canberra, ACT, Australia
  • 2CSIRO Climate Science Centre, Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organization, Melbourne, VIC, Australia
  • 3Faculty of Science, Engineering and Built Environment, Deakin University, Geelong, VIC, Australia

This paper explores methods and the key factors influencing socio-economic analysis of the role of climate services in disaster risk reduction, with a regional emphasis on Small Island Developing States in the western tropical Pacific. We analyse the role of traditional benefit-cost analysis especially in the context of evaluating the importance of science-based climate change services (i.e., relevant to current and future climate change over multi-decadal timescales) in disaster risk reduction at a national economy level. Our analysis is premised on a range of relevant social and economic metrics at a national economy scale, including surrogate indicators for specific disaster risk reduction sensitive sectors in context of both mitigation (transitional risk) and adaptation (physical risk) to climate change. Relative importance of different methodologies of socio-economic analysis (i.e., partial/sectoral vs economy-wide modelling), gaps in relevant data and information, and the role of the public and private sectors in mobilising resources and capability for facilitating such analysis are explored. Our paper also discusses the issues relating to investing in, producing and undertaking on-ground applications associated with disaster risk reduction using climate change services for both public good and private (-for-profit) benefit outcomes, and provides suggestions for further research to improve socio-economic analysis of Climate Information Services impacts.

Introduction

Numerous studies have provided strong evidence of the social, economic and environmental benefits of weather and climate services (Zillman, 1999; Freebairn and Zillman, 2002; Gunasekera, 2004; World Meteorological Organisation, 2015), hereafter referred to collectively as Climate Information Services (CIS). In this context, reference to CIS in this paper broadly aligns with the definition of CIS described by the EU Roadmap for Climate Services (European Commission 2015).

CIS transform climate and weather data into tailored information and knowledge that help users. They enable users to make informed decisions across different sectors and activities. Given the increasing impacts of climate-related natural disasters around the world (e.g., Coronese et al., 2019), and in the Pacific specifically (e.g., Kumar 2020), provision of relevant climate services is regarded as an important activity that can help Pacific Small Island Developing States (SIDS) in climate and weather-related disaster risk reduction (DRR) (SPREP 2016; Cheng et al., 2020). We explore different methods (i.e., partial/sectoral vs economy-wide modelling) and key factors influencing socio-economic analysis of the role of climate services in DRR here.

By contrast, there is also a body of opinion questioning the efficacy of CIS to inform adaptation planning and associated decision-making more generally, including at a sectoral level in the Pacific (Webber 2017, 2019; Webber and Donner, 2017).

Given this background, the key objective of this paper is (by using a case study) to estimate the socio-economic effects of CIS-based improved decision-making around investment and protection of coastal assets and infrastructure in Pacific SIDS. Our analysis will provide a useful illustration of a rigorous and systematic framework for evaluating the net socio-economic benefits of CIS to decision-makers, including donors, national governments and CIS user groups, funding agencies, internal stakeholders, user groups and local communities. Furthermore, we anticipate that our research will build increased understanding and awareness of the role and value of so-called ‘“next generation”’ CIS (Jacobs and Street 2020) among climate scientists, national meteorological and hydrological services, the DRR sector and associated CIS user communities, with learnings for both developing countries/SIDs and developed countries where appropriate.

The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. In the next section, we present the methodological framework used in this study. Following on from this we provide a brief discussion of our analysis. In Methodological Framework, the main results of our analysis are presented. The final section provides a policy discussion associated with our key findings.

Materials and Methods

Role and Value of CIS

Assessing the role and value of CIS presents several challenges. The analysis presented in this paper is necessarily therefore predicated on explicit assumptions. Firstly, majority of CIS are produced and delivered as a public good. More specifically, they are a service provided without intended explicit commercial profit to all members of a society, either by the government or by a private firm or an organization and funded by the government. Secondly, CIS are both non-excludable and non-rivalrous. This implies that individuals cannot be effectively excluded from their use and use by one individual does not diminish their availability or value to others. Thirdly, the value of CIS improves with the investment in skill, resolution and capability of the basic meteorological and climatological data and information generated by relevant observations and models on the further assumption that 1) such data and information is tailored to the specific needs of users, and 2) the cost of which is generally borne by government or those providing the public good. Finally, the downstream benefits that accrue to end-users include for both public good and in many cases private-for-profit; the latter of which occurs when core CIS products and services are utilised as the primary input for development of more differentiated products and services, typically by and/or for the private sector.

CIS are an intermediate good and an enabling technology that adds value to other goods and services. To understand their value, we need to explore the benefits that users draw from CIS. Estimating the consumer surplus through willingness to pay for CIS (using a partial equilibrium framework) is one approach to assessing their value. Consumer surplus is the difference between the price a consumer is prepared to pay for a good or service and the price that the consumer has to pay. This approach has been used in a number of studies attempting to value CIS (see Ouédraogo et al., 2018; Tesfaye et al., 2020).

An alternative approach is to examine the impact of CIS as an enabling technology on productivity of downstream users/sectors of the services (see Newth et al., 2017; Naab et al., 2019). The productivity impacts are then translated into an increase in value added in a sector. In this paper we adopt the productivity approach (using a general equilibrium framework) to assessing the value of CIS. This approach was chosen, as within an economy wide framework, the full implications of changes in productivity can be accounted, giving a wider prospective on the benefits and value of CIS, without having to explicitly model the CIS sector.

Methodological Framework

General equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by assuming that a set of prices exist that will result in an overall equilibrium, where supply equals demand (See Appendix A1 for more details). General equilibrium theory is distinguished from partial equilibrium theory by the fact that it attempts to look at several markets simultaneously rather than a single market or sector of a market in isolation. As an example, in the agricultural sector, if producers use seasonal forecasting (as a CIS) to improve the productivity (both in terms of quantity and quality) of the production of agricultural commodities, then producers will have a competitive advantage over competitors. This allows them to maintain or increase supply. Our methodological framework is an economy-wide modelling framework or a computable general equilibrium (CGE) modelling framework.

The major advantage of general equilibrium modelling is that it tracks all the relationships between supply side factors (such as availability of labour, infrastructure, other inputs and technology) and demand side factors (prices, change in quantity demanded). A number of studies have used CGE models to assess the implications of a changing climate on agricultural productivity (Cai et al., 2015), labour productivity (Newth et al., 2015), changes in patterns of crop production (Porfirio et al., 2017), and the impact of ENSO on agricultural productivity (Araújo et al., 2015).

The CGE model that we have used here is the Global Trade and Analysis Project (GTAP) model, a widely used general equilibrium model (see Hertel, 1997). GTAP Model has been used by over 400 government and international research and donor organizations and a host of academic and private sector organizations across the world for many decades. The standard Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model used in this study is a multi-region, multi-sector, computable general equilibrium model. For a full account of the key GTAP model assumptions and equations, the reader is directed to Hertel (1997) and Valenzuela et al. (2008).

For understanding the whole of economy implications of CIS and the flow of effects of productivity changes, the GTAP model is a logical choice. The GTAP model gives users are wide range of options for understanding economy effects such as unemployment, tax revenue, trade obstacles, and productivity, which map naturally to understanding the benefits of CIS. GTAP also allows for partial equilibrium closures, which facilitate the comparison of results to studies between partial equilibrium assumptions, so sector specific modelling results around the use of CIS can be included within the GTAP framework to provide more detailed analysis.

In more detail, the GTAP model assumes constant returns to scale and perfect competition in all the markets with Walrasian adjustment to ensure a general equilibrium. As illustrated in Figure 1 (based on Brockmeier, 2001; Hertel et al., 2010), each region has a representative household that collects all the income in its region and spends it over three expenditure types: private household (consumer), government and savings, in accordance with a Cobb-Douglas utility function.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. A schematic illustration of the standard GTAP Model (Source: Hertel et al. (2010) after Brockmeier (2001).

Each sector is modelled by a representative firm that maximizes profits subject to a nested Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function. The CES production function combines primary factors and intermediate inputs to produce the sector’s final good.

Firms pay wages/rental rates to the regional household in return for the employment of land, labour, capital and natural resources. Firms sell their output to other firms (intermediate inputs), to private households, government and investment. Firms also export tradable commodities and import tradable goods and intermediate inputs from other regions. These goods are assumed to be differentiated by region, following the Armington assumption, and hence the model can track bilateral trade flows.

The GTAP database version of the model used in this paper comprises 140 regions, and 57 sectors of the global trade analysis project database, version 9 (Aguiar et al., 2016). The model was run with the standard comparative static model closure, allowing for the analysis of policy changes relative to what would otherwise be.

There were three main steps in conducting the study:

• Developing the GTAP model aggregation that represented the key sectoral and regional economic activities;

• Establishing a reference case or a baseline, against which the counterfactuals will be evaluated; and

• Establishing the counterfactual scenarios.

We undertook ground-truthing of this approach, along with relevant assumptions and applicability of the analysis described here, in part using a stakeholder engagement process involving various in-country stakeholder meetings held in Vanuatu as part of the Green Climate Fund project entitled “Climate Information Services for Resilient Development Planning in Vanuatu” (https://www.greenclimate.fund/project/fp035). This project is designed to develop and deliver CIS to inform climate action and associated decision making at a sectoral and local community level.

Regional and Sectoral Aggregation

The GTAP model is based on the GTAP database, with economy-wide information for 140 regions across the world and 57 sectors of each economy/region. To make the analysis more tractable, it is necessary to aggregate the sectors and regions into larger regions. As we are interested in the impacts of protection of coastal assets and infrastructure from sea level rise on Pacific SIDS, we have created 1) an aggregation that has Pacific SIDS as a separate region (named as Rest of Oceania or XOC), although this is itself an aggregate region, 2) its main trading and foreign aid partners, and 3) similar collection of island nations (for comparison) and 4) other major geographical and economic regions. The aggregation is described in Table 1. We have aggregated the industry sectors of each economy/region into 14 sectors and they are listed in Table 2. We note that alternative aggregations are possible, and aggregations should be determined by the question under investigation.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Regional Aggregation for the GTAP model.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. Sectoral Aggregation for the GTAP model.

The reference case has been defined as the prevailing situation with existing CIS data and information from meteorological and climatological service providers, including from existing, basic infrastructure. The reference case scenario represents as closely as possible the likely changes expected to occur in the global economy consisting of the countries/regions covered in the GTAP model database. These changes in the global economy are grouped into two areas: the first deals with the macro economic forecasts of each country/region and the second deals with expected policy changes. The key macroeconomic variables covered include gross domestic product (GDP), gross domestic investment and population and labour force projections. The reference case assumes that there is no impact of climate change on the underlying economic parameters and settings. The key policy changes relate to trade policy changes at multilateral, regional and bilateral levels converting major sectors/industries across the world with a particular focus on major trading partners. The major purpose here is to develop a realistic base case scenario for the global economy.

Counterfactual Scenario

To illustrate the economic implications of global sea level rise from climate change and the potential avoidable socio-economic damages, we made use of two counterfactual scenarios. The first counterfactual assumed that the current level of investment in basic CIS is maintained, and that based on this information decision makers are able to make decisions about future infrastructure, economic investments and coastal adaptation measures. These decisions are far from optimal. We will refer to this case as the “sea level rise scenario”.

The second additional government investment in CIS, which is invested into the existing CIS sector, and additional payments to the construction sector to implement the required mitigation steps. In this scenario, an additional investment in tailored CIS is provided to support sectoral decision-making around coastal adaptation and infrastructure investments. These decisions are assumed to be more effective than those made under the “sea level rise scenario”, but there are still unavoidable affects from sea level rise. We will refer to this as the ‘“mitigated sea level rise scenario”’.

Table 3 lists the assumed key economic shocks and policy changes associated with these two counterfactual scenarios used in this study using the GTAP model. In each case the productivity of the sector was targeted by the shock. It should be realized that the chosen values of the economic shocks and policy changes are illustrative and indicative only from the consultation process. The impact of climate change is governed by a 2°C of warming above pre-industrial levels. As the GTAP model is comparative static, we are concerned that the level of warming has occurred rather than when it will occur. The selection of values was done via stakeholder engagement and the availability of background information.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 3. Policy shocks used in modelling.

Results

The key results of our analysis are presented in Figures 24. As illustrated in Figure 2, the gross domestic product (GDP) of the Pacific SIDS represented by the Rest of Oceania (XOC) region in the GTAP model is estimated to fall by 8 percent under the sea level rise scenario and 3.5% under the mitigated sea level rise scenario relative to the baseline or reference case. They equate to US$ 3.5 b and US$ 1.5 b, respectively. This is in comparison to the reference case GDP level of US$ 44 b for the Rest of Oceania region. Our analysis indicates that at the aggregate regional level, mitigation of sea level rise is estimated to save US$2 b (in terms of potential losses) relative to what would otherwise be. It is important to recognize that the sea level rise mitigation impacts will vary across the individual Pacific SIDS depending on their level of vulnerability with some countries receiving disproportionately higher impacts than others. Hence, from an empirical point of view, it will be an important step in future GTAP data base development to disaggregate the region into individual countries of the Pacific SIDS.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. Comparison of the GDP outcomes for the two counterfactual scenarios.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. Changes in sectoral output relative to the baseline.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. Change in household incomes.

The GTAP model tracks the changes in output of each sector of the economy resulting from specific policy shocks. These estimated sectoral output changes relative to the baseline are shown Figure 3. Under both the sea level rise scenario and the mitigated sea level rise scenarios, outputs of most of the sectors are estimated to decline relative to the baseline levels. Fall in outputs are driven by the loss in sectoral productivity and increased transport costs associated with effects of sea level rises in general. However, it is important to note that loss in sectoral outputs is smaller under mitigated sea level rise scenario relative to the sea level rise scenario.

Figure 4 illustrates the changes in household incomes for the sea level rise scenario and the mitigated sea level rise scenario. Under the sea level rise scenario, household income is estimated to fall by an average of US$612 per household, while under the mitigation of sea level rise scenario the reduction is estimated to be US$276 per household. This in turn is expected to have a significant impact on household income in individual Pacific SIDS. To put this in context, for example, the Vanuatu household income expenditure survey lists the average household income to be between $US8,511 and US$10,585. Again, it is important to recognize that the reduction in household income estimated here is at the aggregate region level. The specific impacts will vary across individual countries, with some countries receiving disproportionately higher impacts than others.

Discussion

Virtually every economy and every industry are directly or indirectly affected by climatic and weather conditions, and these impacts are increasing due to climate change (e.g., Coronese et al., 2019). Climate and weather data and information in the form of CIS acquires economic value by influencing the behaviour of users whose activities are sensitive to climatic and weather conditions. Hence, it logically follows that CIS can be used to mitigate the risks and impacts of climate change. Such information provides the evidence-base for improved policy development, planning and associated decision-making underpinning national, regional, and household-level adaptation to events such as sea level rise and various climate-related natural disasters. Developing economies such as those in the Pacific SIDS can be disproportionately affected by the effects of climate and weather. These effects include impacts on economic activity, household income and well-being of local communities etc.

The analysis presented in this paper illustrates that the use of CIS-based improvements to DRR decision making could potentially help lower the adverse impacts of sea level rise in the Pacific SIDS. This can be in relation to investment and protection of coastal assets and infrastructure in Pacific SIDS. Our analysis has shown that even modest reductions in the impact of such events have considerable socio-economic and welfare implications for the regions affected. For example, under the “mitigation of sea level rise” scenario the estimated reduction in GDP and average household income in Pacific SIDS are much lower (3.5% and US $276) than under the “sea level rise” scenario (8% and US$ 612), respectively.

This highlights the importance of allocating adequate resources for supporting the development and delivery of CIS on a sustained basis concurrently with strategic climate finance investment in adaptation and disaster risk reduction. It is also the case that the public-good/private-for-public nexus in relation to CIS in developing countries such as Pacific SIDS is entirely compatible on the assumption that 1) core CIS products and services benefitting all of society should be publicly funded to address relevant market failure on a needs basis, and 2) that the additional investment required for differentiated CIS products and services can/should be funded by the private sector where there are clear private-for-profit imperatives at play; noting in particular that so-called “commercialisation” of climate science (e.g., as referred by Webber and Donner 2017) in and of itself is not problematic as long as the associated science-based CIS delivery is appropriately balanced, accessible and the funding burden equitably distributed across the CIS value chain.

The limitations of CIS in providing tangible benefits to ultimate on-ground beneficiaries such as in the Pacific are well recognized (Webber 2017; 2019), and this paper makes no attempt to further elucidate the additional requirements for ensuring CIS are appropriately tailored to meet the priority needs of users. Rather it is assumed that best practice delivery of CIS is followed by providers, including compliance with contemporary principles of co-design and co-production of CIS with users as mainstream service delivery process. Like-wise this study makes no attempt to expand on the broader evidence and associated data/information sources required to ensure a multi-disciplinary approach to effective and efficient CIS delivery. It is however assumed that such outcomes require multiple lines of evidence of which CIS is but one, albeit we believe a critical component. It follows that to achieve the types of societal outcomes described in this paper, the CIS process more broadly needs to be optimized, including along lines suggested by Webber (2017; 2019) and more recently by Jacobs and Street (2020) in relation to so-called “next generation” climate services.

Furthermore, the analysis of the socio-economic costs and benefits of the use of CIS needs to be recognized as an ongoing process. Such analysis will have several policy implications in terms of providing valuable evidenced based information to help 1) frame the planning and policymaking dialogue with government and other stakeholders at sectoral and community level, 2) demonstrate the net socio-economic and environmental return on investment, 3) provide a quantifiable decision-making framework through which investment in climate services can be made, and 4) provide a monitoring and evaluation capability for demonstrating the long-term net socio-economic impact of CIS.

In the context of the analysis undertaken in this paper there are several areas where further modelling improvements can be made. These are areas for future research. The first area of improvement relates to the explicit treatment of CIS in our modelling work. Currently our modelling would assume that all changes to CIS are exogenously driven, that is, the basic costs and benefits are calculated off the model and then used to form the reference case and the counterfactual scenarios. An alternative approach is to create a CIS sector within our model, and then further activate that sector directly with changes in policy through increased funding, new infrastructure and investment, etc. The model would then endogenously calculate the associated productivity changes. This approach would still require exogenous calculations of the impacts of climate phenomena such as the impact of sea level rise on infrastructure. This expansion would allow us to explore issues such as the implication of reduced/increased government funding for CIS on the mitigation of sea level rise.

The second area of improvement relates to the disaggregation of Pacific SIDS in our model. The GTAP database linked to the GTAP model has 147 countries and regions. These regions can be aggregated and disaggregated in appropriate ways to answer key policy and economic questions. In this paper, the Pacific Islands were aggregated together to form the “Rest of Oceania” or XOC. Disaggregation of XOC into smaller economies is possible and it would allow a more robust analysis of the beneficiaries of different types of CIS. This can be done in one of two ways. First via creating regional households within the modelling framework, where we could see the household-level effects. This is plausible as the required information such as the Vanuatu Household Expenditure Survey (see https://vnso.gov.vu/index.php/census-and-surveys/surveys/household-income-expenditure-survey-hies) is available. Second way is to split Pacific Island Countries out so they have a distinct country and sectoral representation. This may be difficult, as the detailed data required may not be available, but it should be possible to construct a good representation of any island nation economy based on reliable proxy data.

Here, we have used scenario analysis of the impact of sea level rise in the Pacific, we illustrate the use of socio-economic analysis as one means of quantifying societal value and benefits of CIS. Such analysis is a legitimate line of evidence (amongst others) to enhance DRR policy development, planning and decision making in the Pacific. The CGE modelling framework presented here is highly flexible, meaning that with methodological improvements in socio-economic, such as more detailed partial sectoral analysis or improved impact analysis, outputs can be easily incorporated into decision-making, thereby leading to more robust analysis and policy making into the future.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary Material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author Contributions

DN, GG and DG, Wrote the paper, DN, DG conducted research, DN GG and DG designed research, DG and DN performed analysis.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

The reviewer EV declared a past co-authorship with the authors DN and DG to the handling Editor.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge the funding support from the Green Climate Fund (GCF) project entitled ‘Climate Information Services for Resilient Development Planning in Vanuatu’ (https://www.greenclimate.fund/project/fp035). Aspects of this manuscript have been previously released as a GCF report by Newth et al. (2017). Colleagues from CSIRO Climate Science Centre including Juliet Bell and Leanne Webb have provided constructive comments on the draft manuscript.

References

Aguiar, A., Narayanan, B., and McDougall, R. (2016). An Overview of the GTAP 9 Data Base. Jgea 1 (1), 181–208. doi:10.21642/jgea.010103af

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Araújo, P., Féres, J., Reis, E., and Braga, M. J. (2015). Assessing the Impacts of ENSO-Related Weather Effects on the Brazilian Agriculture. Proced. Econ. Finance 24, 146–155. doi:10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00635-8

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Brockmeier, M. (2001). A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model. GTAP Technical Paper No. 8, March Available at: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/181.pdf. (Accessed October 1, 2021).

Google Scholar

Cai, Y., Newth, D., Finnigan, J. J., and Gunasekera, D. (2015). A Hybrid Energy-Economy Model for Global Integrated Assessment of Climate Change Carbon Mitigation and Energy Transformation. Appl. Energy 148, 381–395. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2015.03.106

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, C.-P., Lin, H.-I., Wang, S., Dean Liu, P.-T., and Camyale Chao, K.-Y. (2020). Climate Services in Asia Pacific: Emerging Trends and Prospects. Bull. Am. Meteorol. Soc. Meet. Summ. 101, E1568–E1571. doi:10.1175/BAMS-D-20-0093.1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Coronese, M., Lamperti, F., Keller, K., Chiaromonte, F., and Roventini, A. (2019). Evidence for Sharp Increase in the Economic Damages of Extreme Natural Disasters. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 116, 21450–21455. doi:10.1073/pnas.1907826116

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

European Commission (2015). A European Research and Innovation Roadmap for Climate Services. Brussels. 51pp: Directorate of Research and Innovation, European Commission.

Google Scholar

Freebairn, J. W., and Zillman, J. W. (2002). Economic Benefits of Meteorological Services Meteorological Applications. Meteorol. App. 9, 33–44. doi:10.1017/S1350482702001044

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gunasekera, D. (2004). Economic Issues Relating to Meteorological Service Provision. Melbourne: Bureau of Meteorology. BMRC Research Report No. 102.

Google Scholar

Hertel, T. W., Burke, M. B., and Lobell, D. B. (2010). The Poverty Implications of Climate-Induced Crop Yield Changes by 2030. Glob. Environ. Change 20, 577–585. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2010.07.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jacobs, K. L., and Street, R. B. (2020). The Next Generation of Climate Services. Clim. Serv. 20, 100199. doi:10.1016/j.cliser.2020.100199

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

L. Kumar (Editor) (2020). Climate Change and Impacts in the Pacific (Switzerland AG: Springer Nature), 538.

Google Scholar

Naab, F. Z., Abubakari, Z., and Ahmed, A. (2019). The Role of Climate Services in Agricultural Productivity in Ghana: The Perspectives of Farmers and Institutions. Clim. Serv. 13, 24–32. doi:10.1016/j.cliser.2019.01.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Newth, D., Gunasekera, D., and Gooley, G. (2017). “Framework for Undertaking Socio-Economic Cost- Benefit Analysis for Climate Information Services in the Western Tropical Pacific,” in Report to the Green Climate Fund Readiness and Preparatory Support (Activity Area 4) for Vanuatu (Readiness GrantAgreement VUT-, 001) (Australia: Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO)).

Google Scholar

Newth, D., Valenzuela, E., Cai, Y., and Gunasekera, D. (2015). “Welfare and Production Implications of Climate Change-Induced Impacts on Labour Capacity: Assessment of Outputs from 30 CMIP5Earth System Models,” in 18th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis; 12-19 June 2015, Melbourne, Australia. Global Trade Analysis Project (West Lafayette, Indiana: Purdue University).

Google Scholar

Ouédraogo, M., Barry, S., Zougmoré, R., Partey, S., Somé, L., and Baki, G. (2018). Farmers' Willingness to Pay for Climate Information Services: Evidence from Cowpea and Sesame Producers in Northern Burkina Faso. Sustainability 10 (3), 611. doi:10.3390/su10030611

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Porfirio, L., Newth, D., Harman, I. N., Finnigan, J. J., and Cai, Y. (2017). Patterns of Crop Cover under Future Climates. Ambio, 46, 265–276. doi:10.1007/s13280-016-0818-1

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

SPREP (2016). Pacific Islands Meteorological Services in Action: A Compendium of Climate Services Case Studies. Secretariat of the Pacific Environmental Programme (SPREP). Apia, Samoa: SPREP. 551. 510996.

Google Scholar

Tesfaye, A., Hansen, J., Kagabo, D., Birachi, E., Radeny, M., and Solomon, D. (2020). Rwanda Climate Services for Agriculture: Farmers Willingness to Pay for Improved Climate Services. Wageningen, Netherlands: CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change. CCAFS Working Paper no. 314Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS).

Google Scholar

T.W. Hertel (Editor) (1997). Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press).

Google Scholar

Valenzuela, E., Anderson, K., and Hertel, T. (2008). Impacts of Trade Reform: Sensitivity of Model Results to Key Assumptions. Ieep 4, 395–420. doi:10.1007/s10368-007-0094-4

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Webber, S. (2017). Circulating Climate Services: Commercializing Science for Climate Change Adaptation in Pacific Islands. Geoforum 85, 82–91. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2017.07.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Webber, S., and Donner, S. (2017). Cautions about Commercialising Climate Science for Adaptation in the Developing World. Wires Clim. Change 8, e424. doi:10.1002/wcc42410.1002/wcc.424

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Webber, S. (2019). Putting Climate Services in Contexts: Advancing Multi-Disciplinary Understandings: Introduction to the Special Issue. Climatic Change 157, 1–8. doi:10.1007/s10584-019-02600-9

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

World Meteorological Organisation (2015). Valuing Weather and Climate: Economic Assessment of Meteorological and Hydrological Services. Geneva, Switzerland: World Meteorological Organisation, WMO-No. 1153, 286pp.

Google Scholar

Zillman, J. W. (1999). The National Meteorological Service. WMO Bull. 48, 129–159.

Google Scholar

Appendix 1 Brief Description of the GTAP Modelling Approach

The standard GTAP model used in this study is a multi-region, multi-sector, computable general equilibrium model. For a full account of the key assumptions and equations, the reader is directed to Hertel (1997) and Valenzuela et al. (2008).

The model assumes constant returns to scale and perfect competition in all the markets with Walrasian adjustment to ensure a general equilibrium.

As illustrated in Figure 1 (based on Brockmeier, 2001; Hertel et al., 2010), each region (e.g., Indonesia) has a representative household that collects all the income in its region and spends it over three expenditure types: private household (consumer), government and savings, in accordance with a Cobb-Douglas utility function.

Each sector is modelled by a representative firm that maximizes profits subject to a nested Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function. The CES production function combines primary factors and intermediate inputs to produce the sector’s final good.

Firms pay wages/rental rates to the regional household in return for the employment of land, labour, capital and natural resources. Firms sell their output to other firms (intermediate inputs), to private households, government and investment. Firms also export tradable commodities and import intermediate inputs from other regions. These goods are assumed to be differentiated by region, following the Armington assumption, and hence the model can track bilateral trade flows.

The GTAP database version of the model used in this paper comprises (140 regions aggregated to) 84 regions (with each of the 10 ASEAN countries as separate regions), and 57 sectors of the global trade analysis project database, version 9 (Aguiar et al., 2016). The model was run with the standard comparative static model closure, allowing for the analysis of policy changes relative to what would otherwise be.

Keywords: climate impacts, economic analysis, climate service, public private partnerhips, pacific island nations

Citation: Newth D, Gooley G and Gunasekera D (2021) Socio-Economic Analysis of Climate Services in Disaster Risk Reduction: A Perspective on Pacific SIDS. Front. Environ. Sci. 9:681747. doi: 10.3389/fenvs.2021.681747

Received: 17 March 2021; Accepted: 01 September 2021;
Published: 26 October 2021.

Edited by:

Folco Giomi, Independent researcher, Padova, Italy

Reviewed by:

Ernesto Valenzuela, Federation University Australia, Australia
Nathaniel K. Newlands, Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada (AAFC), Canada

Copyright © 2021 Newth, Gooley and Gunasekera. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: David Newth, David.newth@csiro.au

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.