Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Energy Res., 25 October 2023
Sec. Sustainable Energy Systems
This article is part of the Research Topic New Trends in Energy-Economy-Environment System View all 21 articles

Research on technological innovation and marketing publicity decision of green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract

Cheng CheCheng CheQing Li
Qing Li*Qi YinQi YinSuhui LiSuhui LiHuixian ZhengHuixian ZhengXin GengXin Geng
  • School of Economics and Management, China University of Petroleum (East China), Qingdao, China

Under the leadership of China’s “dual-carbon” policy, how to reduce energy consumption, reduce carbon emissions, and realize intelligent, low-carbon development has become a key issue faced by the home appliance industry. Studies have shown that green intelligent home appliances can save electricity and reduce carbon emissions. In the context of China’s “dual-carbon” goal, this study examines the technological innovation and marketing publicity decisions of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering the consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract. By constructing a three-level supply chain model that includes home appliance manufacturers, retailers, and consumers, we use the Stackelberg game method to study the decision-making models under four scenarios with and without consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract and consider the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on the supply chain optimal decision. Through model solving and further numerical simulation, the results show that 1) the increase of consumers’ green intelligent preference and consumers’ green marketing sensitivity can produce positive spillover effects and promote the improvement of home appliance manufacturers’ technological innovation efforts and retailers’ marketing publicity efforts; 2) consumer subsidy is always beneficial for the green intelligent development of the supply chain, which can effectively increase the total revenue of the supply chain; 3) the reasonable cost-sharing ratio can stimulate the enthusiasm of supply chain enterprises to increase technological innovation and marketing publicity investments and increase the total profit of the supply chain. However, the excessive cost-sharing ratio frustrates the enthusiasm of home appliance retailers to participate in the coordination, which results in a decline in the overall benefit of the supply chain; 4) by considering both consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract, a reasonable level of consumer subsidy and cost-sharing ratio have a better incentive effect on the supply chain members than in the other three scenarios. This study can provide a broader reference for the green intelligent development of China’s home appliance industry, which plays an important role in the implementation of China’s “dual carbon” goal.

1 Introduction

In response to the global climate problem, the Chinese government proposed a “dual carbon” goal in 2020 (Hu, 2021) and made a series of policy adjustments around this goal. This is a major challenge and an unprecedented opportunity for the home appliance industry. According to the “Annual Report on the State of Global Energy and Carbon Emissions” released by the International Energy Agency (IEA), home appliances are the second largest source of residential energy consumption and account for over 20% of the electricity consumption, while residential carbon emissions account for more than 30% (Yu, 2021). In addition, according to the statistics of the China Household Electrical Appliances Association (CHEAA) and the current trend of the energy consumption development of home appliances such as refrigerators, microwave ovens, water heaters, and washing machines, it is estimated that the country’s hydrofluorocarbon emissions will exceed 25 million tons of CO2 equivalent by 2030, and this number will further increase to 30 million tons of CO2 equivalent by 2060 (Deng, 2021). It is a pressing issue for the home appliance industry on how to reduce the energy consumption and carbon emissions of home appliances. Compared with traditional home appliances, green intelligent home appliances can save electricity and reduce carbon emissions. Hu et al. (2023) have also showed that intelligentization is the key to green and low-carbon transformation. Therefore, intelligentization is a necessary path for the transformation and upgradation of the traditional home appliance industry.

Realizing the intelligent manufacturing of home appliances and promoting green and intelligent development of the home appliance industry depend on green technological innovation. In terms of the current development of the home appliance industry, on the whole, the level of green technological innovation in China’s home appliance enterprises is low, and there will be much room left to make further progress (Tong, 2020). In addition, it is also very important to do a good job in the marketing of green intelligent home appliances. In the actual marketing environment, the perceived value of a product can be used as a result of consumers’ evaluation of the product, which in turn affects their purchase intentions (Li et al., 2020). Alejandre et al. (2022) show that it is better for traditional home appliances to adopt new designs with improved energy-saving models in order to minimize the environmental burden associated with the manufacture of new products. Based on customer-perceived value perspective, Li and Pan (2019) took home appliance retail enterprises as the research object, created a marketing dual-channel synergistic performance evaluation model, and combined it with the fuzzy comprehensive evaluation method to evaluate the O2O marketing synergistic performance of Suning Tesco. The results showed that home appliance retail enterprises have to attach great importance to the pre-sale shopping perception links of consumers in the process of O2O marketing synergistic performance improvement. Jafari (2023) used game theory to conduct research, and the results showed that government support policies can improve the energy saving level of home appliances. Lou and Ma (2018) investigated the complexity of sale and carbon reduction efforts in two parallel appliance supply chain models. We also know that consumer’s green preferences influence enterprise decisions (Long et al., 2022). Therefore, the green and intelligent development of the home appliance industry requires upstream and downstream enterprises of the home appliance supply chain to continuously innovate technology, produce green intelligent home appliances, sell green intelligent home appliances to consumers through marketing publicity, cultivate consumers’ preference for green intelligent home appliances, and increase consumers’ willingness to purchase in future competitions.

However, the input to improve the level of green technological innovation of enterprises will increase enterprises’ cost burden, which hinders the green and intelligent development of the industry to a certain extent. So it requires green effort cost-sharing among supply chain enterprises (Ghosh and Shah, 2015). In the study of green supply chain coordinated innovation and cooperation strategy, Sun and Zhang (2020) found that the cost-sharing contract, as an incentive mechanism, can increase the green innovation inputs of supporting enterprises, optimal returns of both parties, and overall returns. Song et al. (2022) showed that the cost-sharing mechanism can coordinate the supply chain participants and make the supply chain members gain higher profits.

In addition, when compared with the price of ordinary home appliances, the price of green intelligent home appliances is also higher, and the higher price will reduce the willingness of consumers to buy. Therefore, countries generally adopt the means of consumer subsidies so as to improve the willingness of consumers to buy. The increasing willingness of consumers to purchase green products will stimulate the market to increase the supply of green products, promote the benign development of the green supply chain, and promote the green transformation and upgradation of the supply chain (Xing et al., 2023). Nie et al. (2021) have evaluated the effectiveness of the current energy-saving subsidy policy to stimulate the purchase of energy-saving household appliances. Song et al. (2019) established a game model in which the government provides subsidies to consumers who use green products and found that the policy can promote the consumption of green products to an optimal level, and high-income groups preferred the government to provide subsidies for green products.

On the basis of previous studies, from the perspective of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain, this study analyzes and discusses the rationality and necessity of home appliance enterprises to increase technological innovation and marketing publicity, and in the four scenarios with and without consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract, further explores the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, and consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on the optimal decision-making of the supply chain. The conclusions of this study to some extent verifies the effectiveness of consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract in promoting green intelligent development of the home appliance industry, which can provide some references for future government policy formulation, a win–win cooperation among home appliance enterprises, and green intelligent development of the home appliance industry.

The main contributions are as follows: first, we establish a three-level green intelligent home appliance supply chain model comprising manufacturers, retailers, and consumers and at the same time incorporate technological innovation and marketing publicity into demand function, as well as study the optimal decision-making of the supply chain under different scenarios and use the Hessian matrix to find the possibility of the existence of the optimal strategy; second, the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, and consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on manufacturers’ technological innovation, retailers’ marketing publicity, and the total profit of the supply chain is comprehensively considered; finally, through the establishment of the Stackelberg game model to analyze different situations, it further broadens the research ideas of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain, enriches related research theories, and provides a little reference for the green intelligent development of the home appliance industry.

2 Literature review

The research related to this study mainly focuses on three aspects: consumer subsidies, cost-sharing contracts, and the home appliance industry and its supply chain. In this section, we will review the relevant literature and point out how our study differs from them.

2.1 Consumer subsidies

In terms of related research on consumer subsidy policies, some scholars have argued the rationality of consumer subsidies. Yang and Zhao (2015) argued that subsidies for energy-saving products can be deducted from the selling price of the products, which can directly reduce the expenditure of consumers on purchasing the products, guide consumers to support low-carbon products, and enable producers to produce low-carbon products or even zero-emission products. Zhao and Wang (2018) reviewed carbon emission reduction policies in the consumption area such as carbon tax, trading mechanism, and subsidies and compared them in three aspects: efficiency, effectiveness, and fairness; they found that the subsidy policy on the consumption side can help consumers choose low-carbon products or even zero-emission products, which in turn leads to energy-saving production. Li and Wang (2023) demonstrated the necessity of implementing subsidy programs in promoting EV sales and identified the optimal subsidies under various market conditions. Some scholars have also studied the effects of consumer subsidies. Huang et al. (2013) studied government subsidies for consumers purchasing electric vehicles, and the results showed that consumer subsidy policies can significantly increase the sales of electric vehicles, which effectively reduces environmental pollution. Sun and Yu (2018) separately established a two-stage game model under two subsidy policies of the government that subsidizes green producers and consumers. It is found that government subsidizing consumers can increase the consumer demand for green products to a greater extent and bring greater benefits to green producers. Long et al. (2022) explored the joint effect of the dominance structure, green sensitivity, and green preference on the manufacturing closed-loop supply chain and showed that increasing government price subsidies is more favorable to market demand and social welfare. In addition, some scholars have also compared consumer subsidies with other subsidies. By using a game theoretical approach, Bian et al. (2020) analyzed the effects of consumer and manufacturer subsidies on incentives for investing in emission reduction technologies in the manufacturing sector. Hong et al. (2021) examined the impact of corporate subsidies and consumer subsidies on green products. Khosroshahi et al. (2021) developed a three-stage game model with three subsidy policies, namely, government subsidies for manufacturers, retailers, and consumers, respectively, and studied the impact of government subsidies and CSR on supply chain pricing, greenness, and transparency. Xu and Duan (2022) explored optimal pricing and green investment strategies of green products under three kinds of subsidy policies, namely, manufacturer subsidy, retailer subsidy, and consumer subsidy, and investigated the conditions for the adoption of blockchain technology (Xu and He, 2022). Wang and Wang (2020) applied a game theory approach and focused on investigating how sales efforts and different government subsidies promoted manufacturers’ carbon emission reductions. Pan et al. (2023) constructed three game models that included no government subsidy, government subsidy to manufacturers, and government subsidy to consumers to study the effects of retailers’ fairness concerns and channel competition on the dual-channel green supply chains’ optimal decision-making and social welfare under different government subsidy strategies.

2.2 Cost-sharing contracts

The study of green supply chain decision-making problems under cost-sharing contracts is also relatively abundant. Yenipazarli (2017) examined the impact of cost-sharing contracts on downstream retailers’ incentives for upstream manufacturers to innovate. Yi and Li (2018a) studied cost-sharing contracts for energy saving and emissions reduction of a supply chain under the conditions of government subsidies and the carbon tax. Chakraborty et al. (2019) introduced the cost-sharing contract into retailer-led quality innovation cooperation, achieving the improvement of supply chain members and overall profits. Xu et al. (2020) studied product greenness and pricing decisions under three green cost-sharing models in the competitive green supply chain environment. Ma et al. (2020) studied cost-sharing contracts for achieving green supply chain coordination based on confidence level rules under uncertain information. Hu et al. (2020) considered a joint competitive innovation game model in which suppliers dominated and retailers shared innovation costs and compared the effects of two research and development (R&D) cost-sharing ratios proposed by retailers on suppliers’ incentives to innovate. Sharm and Jain (2021) studied cost-sharing contract when the dominant player had fairness preferences under different power structures of the green supply chain. Liu (2021) comparatively investigated the effects of product greenness and big data investment costs on green supply chain pricing strategies and profits under three cost-sharing models, considering both big data investment costs and green technology R&D costs. Qin et al. (2021) investigated the game of environmental cost allocation in the green supply chain under fair preferences. The results showed that retailers’ participation in environmental cost allocation increases the greenness level of products and make the whole supply chain Pareto optimal and strong fairness preferences of the manufacturers weakens the positive effect of retailers’ participation in the supply chain on cost allocation. Lin and Liu (2022) explored the effects of government subsidies and firms’ cost sharing on the level of green efforts, pricing strategies, and profits in the green supply chain. Fan et al. (2023) considered how to design a quality cost-sharing contract to incentivize product quality level improvement and integrate resources (Xu et al., 2021; Xu et al., 2022a). Wang and Wang (2020) studied the long-term cooperative emission reduction, low-carbon publicity, and government subsidies in a low-carbon supply chain based on a differential game model. Lou et al. (2020) investigated low-carbon emission reduction and publicity decision-making of supply chain in the context of different leaders. Meanwhile, they also studied the decision-making model of supply chain enterprises to encourage enterprises to carry out emission reduction innovation through contracts. Yu et al. (2020) explored the effectiveness of carbon emission reduction investment behavior in supply chain enterprises based on cost-sharing coordination under cost subsidy.

2.3 Home appliance industry and its supply chain

At present, the following scholars have conducted relevant research on the technological innovation and marketing publicity in the home appliance industry and home appliance supply chain. Yan (2010) pointed out that it is urgent for home appliance enterprises to implement green procurement, which is of great significance in improving product competitiveness and implementing sustainable development, and green technology innovation is the key link of implementing green procurement. Shen et al. (2012) have detailed how to use experiential marketing to create corporate value in downstream supply chain management of home appliance enterprises. Ma and Zhao (2013) studied the impact of trade-in subsidy on the production and consumption of home appliances. The results showed that policy incentives can effectively boost manufacturers’ profits and further promote the research and development of green appliances. Guo and Zheng (2019) in a systematic discussion on the capability upgrading problems faced by home appliance firms in the context of open innovation have made it clear that catching up with technology is the key (Xu et al., 2022b; Xu and Wei, 2023). Yu et al. (2021) constructed a manufacturer-led dual-channel low-carbon supply chain competition and cooperation game and analyzed the effects of energy efficiency ratio, retailers’ sales effort, consumption channel preferences, and manufacturers’ fairness concerns on manufacturers' and retailers’ decisions and revenue. Lv and Huang (2021) provided an empirical test for the conclusion that demand promotes innovation in the home appliance industry, whereby foreseeable future market demand both effectively promotes innovation inputs and enhances innovation outputs. Li et al. (2021) constructed a tripartite game model among the government, home appliance enterprises, and consumers and found that the government’s carbon emission reduction subsidies can improve the innovation ability of enterprises. Lei et al. (2022) showed that income growth will drive home appliance enterprises to transform toward intelligentization and low carbonization.

Finally, we have made a detailed comparison of the related literature, which is shown in Table 1. We can find that the aforementioned studies have conducted a great deal of research on the supply chain and home appliance industry and have achieved certain results. However, most of the current literature discusses manufacturers’ technological innovation or retailers’ marketing publicity from the perspective of the home appliance industry and home appliance supply chain, and few scholars consider both at the same time and incorporate them into the demand function. In terms of government subsidies to the home appliance industry, there are few literature studies on consumer subsidies. However, in real life, the government subsidizes consumers who buy appliances that meet green and intelligent requirements. Therefore, it is necessary to study the impact of consumer subsidies on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decisions. On this basis, studies combining cost-sharing contract with technological innovation, marketing publicity, and consumer subsidy are even rarer. The Stackelberg game model is widely used in the supply chain’s optimal decision problem and further through numerical simulation to validate the results of the model and increase the reliability of the model and its conclusions; for example, Lou and Ma’s (2018) research on the decision-making of sales and carbon reduction effort in the home appliance supply chain and Cao et al.'s (2020) comparative study of supply chain green effort decisions based on different government subsidy strategies. Therefore, based on the aforementioned analysis, this study starts from the green intelligent home appliance supply chain, incorporates technological innovation and marketing publicity into the demand function, considers the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preferences, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, and consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract and explores technological innovation and marketing publicity issues of the home appliance industry. The main research problem of this study is to explore the optimal decision-making problem for each subject of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain under the four models, verify the effectiveness of the Chinese government’s consumer subsidy policy, and draw conclusions based on the model’s results and numerical simulation to provide a reference for practice.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Comparison of the literature.

3 Problem description and model assumptions

3.1 Problem description

In order to explore technological innovation and marketing publicity decisions of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain by considering consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract, this study constructs a three-level green intelligent home appliance supply chain model that consists of manufacturers who carry out technological innovation, retailers who are responsible for marketing publicity, and consumers. In this supply chain, home appliance manufacturers are in the dominant position followed by home appliance retailers, constituting the Stackelberg game. Home appliance manufacturers produce green intelligent home appliances with unit cost c through technological innovation and sell them to home appliance retailers at wholesale price ω, and home appliance retailers sell them to consumers at retail price p through marketing publicity to maximize profits. However, the ever-increasing costs of technological innovation hinder manufacturers from investing in technological innovation efforts. In order to encourage home appliance manufacturers to increase technological innovation investment, home appliance retailers have the motivation to share some technological innovation costs of home appliance manufacturers, thereby improving decision-making levels and achieving supply chain coordination. The government provides subsidies to consumers who purchase green intelligent home appliances to increase the product market demand, thereby affecting the optimal decision-making of home appliance supply chain members. In addition, we assume that consumers have green preferences, and their demands are affected by the level of product technology innovation, product marketing publicity, and product prices.

Therefore, this study uses the Stackelberg game method to analyze and compare game models of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain under four scenarios without considering consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract (Model D), considering the consumer subsidy (Model M), considering cost-sharing contract (Model C), and considering both consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract (Model U) and focuses on the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on the supply chain upstream and downstream home appliance enterprises technological innovation and marketing publicity and the total profit of the supply chain. The green intelligent home appliance supply chain game model is shown in Figure 1.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. Green intelligent home appliance supply chain game model diagram.

3.2 Model hypotheses

Assumption 1. In order to improve the green intelligent level of home appliances, home appliance manufacturers increase the technological innovation investment. We assume that the technological innovation costs of home appliance manufacturers is ηφ2/2 (Xue et al., 2019; Lin and Liu, 2022), where η is the cost coefficient of technological innovation and φ is the level of technological innovation efforts.

Assumption 2. In order to guide consumers’ preference for green intelligent home appliances, home appliance retailers increase marketing publicity investments. We assume that the marketing publicity costs of home appliance retailers is λA2/2 (Lou and Ma, 2018; Yuan et al., 2022), where λ is the cost coefficient of marketing publicity and A is the level of marketing publicity efforts.

Assumption 3. Members of the home appliance supply chain produce green intelligent home appliances according to the quantity determined by the market demand function, and the products can be completely cleared. We assume that the green intelligent home appliance market demand function is abp+βφ+γA (Yi and Li, 2018a; Sun and Zhong, 2023), where a is the market capacity, b is the consumer’s price sensitivity coefficient, p is the retail price of the product market, β is consumer’s green intelligent preference coefficient, and γ is consumer’s green marketing sensitivity coefficient.

Assumption 4. In order to encourage consumers to purchase green intelligent home appliances, the government subsidizes for consumers an amount of s, which will directly affect the price of products purchased by consumers, and the actual purchase price of consumers is ps (Wang and Wang, 2023; Xing et al., 2023). For example, Shanghai provides consumers with a one-time subsidy of 10% of the payment amount and up to 1,000 yuan for personal consumption such as purchasing green intelligent home appliances.

Assumption 5. In order to encourage home appliance manufacturers to increase technological innovation investment, home appliance retailers have the motivation to share some technological innovation costs of home appliance manufacturers, thereby improving the decision-making levels and achieving supply chain coordination. When home appliance manufacturers and retailers reach a cost-sharing contract, the ratio of technological innovation costs share by retailers is θ (Yi and Li, 2018b; Ma et al., 2020) and the ratio share by manufacturers is 1θ.

3.3 Model parameters

All parameters involved in this study and their definitions are summarized in Table 2.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. Symbol parameter.

4 Decision model and result analysis of green intelligent home appliance supply chain

4.1 Decentralized decision-making of green intelligent home appliance supply chain (Model D)

First, home appliance manufacturers decide the level of technological innovation efforts and wholesale prices of green intelligent home appliances, while retailers then decide the retail prices and level of marketing publicity efforts of green intelligent home appliances, and the goal of both the decisions is to maximize their own profits. The profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers is as follows:

πMd=ωcabp+βφ+γA12ηφ2,(1)
πRd=pωabp+βφ+γA12λA2.(2)

We use the reverse induction method to calculate the second-order partial derivative of and on Formula 2 and get the Hessian matrix as follows: H=2bγγλ=γ2 +2bλ.

Therefore, when 2b<0 and γ2 +2b >0, the profit function of home appliance retailers is a concave function of p and A, and there is an optimal solution. Let the first derivation be equal to 0 and be solved simultaneously to get

pd*=ωγ2+a+bω+βφλγ2+2bλ,(3)
Ad*=abω+βφγγ2+2bλ.(4)

Then, substitute (3–4) into (1) and calculate the second-order partial derivative of ω and φ, respectively; the Hessian matrix is obtained as follows:

H=4b2λ2γ2+4bλ2bλβ2γ2+4bλ2bλβ2γ2+4bλ2ηγ22bλ2γ2+4bλ=b2λ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2γ22bλ2.

Therefore, when 2b2λγ22bλ<0 and b2λ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2γ22bλ2>0, the profit function of home appliance manufacturers is a concave function of ω and φ, and there is an optimal solution. Let the first derivation be equal to 0, and when solved simultaneously, we can get

ωd*=a+bcηγ2+2bλbcλβ2b2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2,(5)
φd*=abcλβ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2.(6)

By substituting (5–6) into (3–4), the values of optimal decision variables p and A are obtained as follows:

pd*=aηγ23bλ+bcηγ2bλ+λβ2b2ηγ22bλ+λβ2,(7)
Ad*=a+bcηγ2ηγ22bλ+λβ2.(8)

By substituting (5–8) into (1–2), we obtain the profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers as follows:

πMd*=abc2ηλ4ηγ2+8bηλ2λβ2,(9)
πRd*=abc2η2λγ2+2bλ22ηγ22bλ+λβ22.(10)

At the same time, we can get the optimal profit function of the home appliance supply chain as follows:

πSCd*=πMd*+πRd*=abc2ηλ3ηγ2+6bηλλβ222ηγ22bλ+λβ22.(11)

Only when ωd*,φd*,pd*,Ad*,πMd*,πRd*,πSCd*>0, home appliance manufacturers and retailers will conduct investment and manufacturing activities, so abc>0 should be satisfied with the following same reasoning.

4.2 Decentralized decision-making of green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering consumer subsidy (Model M)

In order to encourage consumers to purchase green intelligent home appliances, the government subsidizes consumers with an amount of s, which will directly affect the price of products purchased by consumers, and the actual purchase price of consumers is ps. The profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers is as follows:

πMm=ωcabps+βφ+γA12ηφ2,(12)
πRm=pωabps+βφ+γA12λA2.(13)

We use the reverse induction method to obtain the optimal decision of ω, φ, p, and A as follows:

ωm*=a+bs+cηγ2+2bλbcλβ2b2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2,(14)
φm*=a+bc+sλβ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2,(15)
pm*=ηa+bsγ23bλ+bcηγ2bλ+λβ2b2ηγ22bλ+λβ2,(16)
Am*=a+bc+sηγ2ηγ22bλ+λβ2.(17)

By substituting (14–17) into (12–13), we obtain the following profit functions of home appliance manufacturers and retailers

πMm*=a+bc+s2ηλ4ηγ2+8bηλ2λβ2,(18)
πRm*=a+bc+s2η2λγ2+2bλ22ηγ22bλ+λβ22.(19)

At the same time, we get the following optimal profit function of the home appliance supply chain:

πSCm*=πMm*+πRm*=a+bc+s2ηλ3ηγ2+6bηλλβ222ηγ22bλ+λβ22.(20)

The derivation process is similar to that mentioned in Section 4.1 and is hence not repeated here.

Corollary 1. In decision-making Model M, under the consumer subsidy policy, the first-order partial derivative of s is obtained as follows:

ωm*s>0,pm*s>0,Am*s>0,φm*s>0,πMm*s>0,πRm*s>0,πSCm*s>0;

Corollary 1 shows that government subsidies to consumers can encourage them to purchase more green intelligent home appliances, and then home appliance manufacturers and retailers can make more green efforts and choose to increase wholesale and retail prices of green intelligent home appliances to make up for their green investments. It can be seen that the consumer subsidy policy can promote the overall low-carbon green benefits and income of the home appliance supply chain.

Proof of Corollary 1. The proof process is as follows:

ωm*s=bηγ2+2bλb2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2>0,pm*s=bηγ23bλb2ηγ24bηλ+λβ2>0,
Am*s=bηγ2ηγ24bηλ+λβ2>0,φm*s=bλβ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2>0,
πMm*s=2babc+bsηλ4ηγ2+8bηλ2λβ2>0,πRm*s=2babc+bsη2λγ2+2bλ22ηγ24bηλ+λβ22>0,
πSCm*s=2babc+bsηλ3ηγ2+6bηλλβ222ηγ24bηλ+λβ22>0.

Through the algebraic operation, we found that when government provides subsidies to consumers, with the increase of consumer subsidy, there is an increase in the wholesale price and technological innovation efforts of the green intelligent home appliances produced by home appliance manufacturers, and the retail price and marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers increase. At the same time, the profits of home appliance manufacturers and retailers, and the total profit of the supply chain increase accordingly. When γ2 +2bλ >0 and 2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established.

4.3 Decentralized decision-making of green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering cost-sharing contract (Model C)

In order to encourage home appliance manufacturers to increase technological innovation investment, home appliance retailers have the motivation to share some technological innovation costs of home appliance manufacturers, thereby improving the decision-making levels and achieving supply chain coordination. When home appliance manufacturers and retailers reach a cost-sharing contract, the ratio of technological innovation costs share by retailers is θ and the ratio share by manufacturers is 1θ. The profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers is as follows:

πMc=ωcabp+βφ+γA121θηφ2,(21)
πRc=pωabp+βφ+γA12λA212θηφ2.(22)

We use the reverse induction method to calculate the second-order partial derivative of Formula 22 and get the Hessian matrix as follows: H=2bγγλ=γ2 +2bλ.

Therefore, when 2b<0 and γ2 +2b >0, the profit function of home appliance retailers is a concave function of p and A, and there is an optimal solution. Let the first derivation equal to zero and be solved simultaneously to get

pc*=ωγ2+a+bω+βφλγ2+2bλ,(23)
Ac*=abω+βφγγ2+2bλ.(24)

We then substitute (23–24) into (21) and calculate the second-order partial derivative of its ω and φ, and the Hessian matrix obtained is as follows:

H=2b2λγ22bλbλβγ2+2bλbλβγ2+2bλ1+θη=b2λ2η1+θγ22bλλβ2γ22bλ2.

Therefore, when 2b2λγ22bλ<0 and b2λ2η1+θγ22bλλβ2γ22bλ2>0, the profit function of home appliance manufacturers is a concave function of ω and φ, and there is an optimal solution. Let the first derivation equal to zero and be solved simultaneously to get

ωc*=a+bcηγ2+2bλ1+θ+bcλβ2b2η1+θγ22bλ+λβ2,(25)
φc*=abcλβ2η1+θγ22bλλβ2.(26)

Substituting (25–26) into (23–24), the values of the optimal decision variables p and A are obtained as follows:

pc*=aηγ23bλ1+θ+bcηγ2bλ1+θbcλβ2b2η1+θγ22bλλβ2,(27)
Ac*=abcηγ1+θ2η1+θγ22bλ+λβ2.(28)

Substituting (25–28) into (21–22), we obtain the profit function of appliance manufacturers and retailers as follows:

πMc*=abc2λη1+θ2λβ24η1+θγ22bλ,(29)
πRc*=abc2ληηγ22bλ1+θ2λθβ222η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22.(30)

At the same time, we get the optimal profit function of the home appliance supply chain as follows:

πSCc*=πMc*+πRc*=abc2λη3ηγ22bλ1+θ2λβ222η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22.(31)

Corollary 2. In the decision-making model C, under the condition of cost sharing of technological innovation, the first-order partial derivative of θ is obtained as follows:

ωc*θ>0,pc*θ>0,Ac*θ>0,φc*θ>0;

Corollary 2 shows that home appliance retailers share the cost of technological innovation, which reduces the cost of technological innovation investment of home appliance manufacturers, and then home appliance manufacturers make more green efforts to improve the innovation level of green intelligent home appliances. At the same time, to ensure profits, home appliance manufacturers choose to increase the wholesale price of green intelligent home appliances. With the rise in the innovation level of green intelligent home appliances, market demand expands, prompting home appliance retailers to improve the level of marketing publicity efforts. At the same time, in order to ensure profits, home appliance retailers tend to increase the retail price of green intelligent home appliances. It can be seen that the introduction of the cost-sharing contract can further increase the enthusiasm in the production and investment of node enterprises in the home appliance supply chain.

Proof of Corollary 2. The proof process is as follows:

ωc*θ=abcbλβ2ηγ2+2bλb2η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22>0,pc*θ=bcabλβ2ηγ23bλb2η1+θγ22bλλβ22>0,
Ac*θ=abcηγλβ22η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22>0,φc*θ=abcλβ2ηγ22bλ2η1+θγ22bλλβ22>0.

Through the algebraic operation, we found that when home appliance retailers share the cost of technological innovation efforts, with the increase in cost-sharing ratio, the wholesale price and technological innovation efforts of the green intelligent home appliances produced by home appliance manufacturers, and the retail price and marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers increase. When γ2 +2bλ >0 and 2η1+θγ22bλλβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established.

Corollary 3. In the decision-making model C, under the condition of cost sharing of technological innovation, the first-order partial derivative of θ is obtained as follows:

When θ<λβ24ηγ2+2bλ, πRc*θ>0, oppose πRc*θ<0; πMc*θ>0;when θ<13, πSCc*θ>0, oppose πSCc*θ<0;

Corollary 3 shows that when home appliance retailers share the cost of technological innovation, as the cost-sharing ratio increases, the cost of technological innovation for home appliance manufacturers gradually decrease and their profits gradually increase. Under a reasonable cost-sharing ratio, although the home appliance retailers bear a part of the technological innovation investment cost of home appliance manufacturers, it promotes the production enthusiasm of home appliance manufacturers, expands market demand, and increases profits of home appliance retailers. However, when the cost-sharing ratio is very high, the cost of home appliance retailers exceeds the profits, and their participation enthusiasm decreases, resulting in a decrease in the overall profits of the home appliance supply chain.

Proof of Corollary 3. The proof process is as follows:

πRc*θ=abc2λ2β2ηλβ24θηγ22bλ22η1+θγ22bλ+λβ23,when θ<λβ24ηγ2+2bλ,πRc*θ>0,oppose πRc*θ<0;πMc*θ=abc22λ2β2η2λβ24η1+θγ22bλ2>0;πSCc*θ=abc2λ2β2η2γ2+2bλ61+θ+422η1+θγ22bλ+λβ23,when θ<13,πSCc*θ>0,oppose πSCc*θ<0.

Through the algebraic operation, we found that when home appliance retailers share the cost of technological innovation, the profits of home appliance manufacturers increase with the increase in cost-sharing ratio; when θ<λβ24ηγ2+2bλ, the retailer’s profit increases, and when θ>λβ24ηγ2+2bλ, the retailer’s profit decreases; when θ<1/3, the total profit of the supply chain increases, and when θ>1/3, the total profit of the supply chain decreases. When γ2 + 2bλ >0 and 2η1+θγ22bλλβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established.

4.4 Decentralized decision-making of green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract (Model U)

We further analyze the impact of consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on the optimal decision-making of home appliance manufacturers and retailers. The profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers is as follows:

πMu=ωcabps+βφ+γA121θηφ2,(32)
πRu=pωabps+βφ+γA12λA212θηφ2.(33)

We use the reverse induction method to obtain the optimal decision of ω, φ, p, and A as follows:

ωu*=a+bc+sηγ2+2bλ1+θ+bcλβ2b2η1+θγ22bλ+λβ2,(34)
φu*=a+bc+sλβ2η1+θγ22bλλβ2,(35)
pu*=ηa+bsγ23bλ1+θ+bcηγ2bλ1+θbcλβ2b2η1+θγ22bλλβ2,(36)
Au*=a+c+sbηγ1+θ2η1+θγ22bλ+λβ2.(37)

By substituting (34–37) into (32–33), we obtain the profit function of home appliance manufacturers and retailers as follows:

πMu*=a+bc+s2λη1+θ2λβ24η1+θγ22bλ,(38)
πRu*=a+bc+s2ληηγ22bλ1+θ2λθβ222η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22.(39)

At the same time, we can get the optimal profit function of the home appliance supply chain as follows:

πSCu*=πMu*+πRu*=a+bc+s2λη3ηγ22bλ1+θ2λβ222η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22.(40)

The derivation process is similar to that mentioned in Section 4.3 and is hence not repeated here.

Corollary 4. For the home appliance supply chain, under a certain cost-sharing ratio, the benefits brought by decentralized decision-making in the green intelligent home appliance supply chain with the consumer subsidy are better than those brought by decentralized decision-making in the green intelligent home appliance supply chain without consumer subsidy, that is, πSCu*>πSCc*.

Proof of Corollary 4. The proof process is as follows:

πSCu*πSCc*=bsbs+2abcλη3ηγ22bλ1+θ2λβ222η1+θγ22bλ+λβ22>0.

When γ2 +2bλ >0 and 3ηγ22bλ1+θ2λβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established.

Corollary 5. For home appliance manufacturers, under a certain amount of consumer subsidies, the benefits brought by decentralized decision-making in the green intelligent home appliance supply chain with cost-sharing contract are better than those brought by decentralized decision-making in the green intelligent appliance supply chain without cost-sharing contract, that is, πMu*>πMm*.

Proof of Corollary 5. The proof process is as follows:

πMu*πMm*=2a+bc+s2λ2β2ηθ2λβ24η1+θγ22bλ4ηγ2+8bηλ2λβ2>0.

When 2ηγ2+4bηλλβ2>0 and 2η1+θγ22bλλβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established.

Corollary 6. In the decision-making model D, the first-order partial derivative of β and γ is obtained as follows:

φd*β>0,Ad*β>0,φd*γ>0,Ad*γ>0.

Corollary 6 shows that with the increase of consumers’ green intelligence preference and green marketing sensitivity, that is, the more the consumers prefer green intelligent home appliances, the more the consumers will want to buy them, which will promote home appliance manufacturers to improve the level of product technological innovation and produce green intelligent home appliances, and promote retailers to improve the level of marketing publicity efforts to meet the market demand.

Proof of Corollary 6. The proof process is as follows:

φd*β=abcλ2ηγ2+4bηλ+λβ22ηγ2+4bηλλβ22>0;φd*γ=abcλβ4ηγ2ηγ2+4bηλλβ22>0;
Ad*β=a+bcηγ2λβ2ηγ24bηλ+λβ22>0;Ad*γ=a+bcη2ηγ24bηλ+λβ22ηγ24bηλ+λβ22>0.

Through the algebraic operation, we found that with the increase in consumers’ green intelligence preference and green marketing sensitivity, the level of technological innovation efforts and marketing publicity efforts increases. When 2ηγ22bλ+λβ2>0, the aforementioned relationship is established. Similarly, in decision Model M, Model C, and Model U, with the increase in consumers’ green intelligence preference and green marketing sensitivity, the level of technological innovation efforts and marketing publicity efforts increases. The proof process is not repeated here.

5 Numerical simulation

In order to better verify the changing relationship between the parameters, this section compares and analyzes the parameters by assigning them. First, we describe and explain the parameters involved in the article in the third part of the problem description and model assumptions. Then, based on these descriptions, we refer to the previous relevant literature and set the values of the fixed parameters (Lou and Ma, 2018; Ma et al., 2020; Xing et al., 2023). These values are as follows: a = 40, b = 1, c = 10, η = 1, λ = 0.8, β = 0.7, and γ = 0.5.

5.1 Impact of consumer subsidy amount s on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making

Within the range of conditions that satisfy the existence of an optimal solution, when θ = 0.33 is taken, we analyze the impact of the consumer subsidy amount on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making. As shown in Figure 2, from Model M and Model U, it is seen that the total profit of the home appliance supply chain increases with the increase in consumer subsidy amount. As shown in Figure 3, from Model M and Model U, it is seen that the level of technological innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers tend to increase as consumer subsidy amount increases. As shown in Figure 4, from Model M and Model U, it is seen that the level of marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers is positively correlated with the consumer subsidy amount. That is to say, as the amount of government subsidy to consumers increases, the total profit of the supply chain, level of technological innovation efforts, and level of marketing publicity efforts increase accordingly, all of which are greater than they are in the case of Model D. Therefore, the consumer subsidy policy can promote the overall green benefits and income of the home appliance supply chain. Corollary 1 is verified. In addition, Figures 24 show that Model U is always higher than Model M, Model C, and Model D, which shows that when the cost-sharing contract is introduced into the home appliance supply chain, the technological innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers, marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers, and total profit of the supply chain in the consumer subsidy scenario are better than that of the other three scenarios. Therefore, consumer subsidy further improves the overall benefit of the home appliance supply chain. Corollary 4 is verified. Finally, Figure 2 shows that when s (0.5,3), Model M is higher than Model C. Figure 4 shows that when s (2.738, 3), Model M is higher than Model C. In Figure 3, Model C is always higher than Model M. This suggests that in the two decision models that consider the impact of consumer subsidy on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making and the impact of cost-sharing contract on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making, consumer subsidy has a more significant impact on the total profit of the supply chain and the level of retailer’s marketing publicity efforts than it does on the cost-sharing contract; and the cost-sharing contract has a more significant impact on the level of the manufacturer’s technological innovation efforts than it does on consumer subsidy.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. Impact of consumer subsidy amount on the total profit of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. Impact of consumer subsidy amount on the level of technological innovation efforts.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. Impact of consumer subsidy amount on the level of marketing publicity efforts.

5.2 Impact of cost-sharing ratio θ on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making

Within the range of conditions that satisfies the existence of the optimal solution, when s = 3 is taken, the impact of the cost-sharing ratio on the home appliance supply chain decision-making is analyzed. Figure 5 shows that in Model C and Model U, the total profit of the home appliance supply chain first increases and then decreases with the increase in cost-sharing ratio, until it is lower than the total profit of the supply chain in Model D and Model M. At θ = 0.33, the total supply chain profit is maximum. Figure 6 shows that in Model C and Model U, the profit of home appliance manufacturers increases with the increase in cost-sharing ratio, and the two are positively correlated. Corollary 3 is verified. In addition, Figure 6 shows that Model U is higher than Model M, Model C, and Model D, which shows that when the government provides a certain amount of consumer subsidy, the profit of the home appliance manufacturers in the cost-sharing contract scenario is better than it is in the other three scenarios. Corollary 5 is verified. It can be seen from Figures 7, 8 that in Model C and Model U, respectively, with the increase in cost-sharing ratio, the technology innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers and the marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers increase accordingly, both of which are greater than in Model D. Therefore, the introduction of the cost-sharing contract can further increase the enthusiasm of production and investment of node enterprises in the home appliance supply chain. Corollary 2 is verified. In addition, Figures 7, 8 show that Model U is always higher than Model M, Model C, and Model D, which shows that when the government provides a certain amount of consumer subsidy, the technological innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers and the marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers in the cost-sharing contract scenario are better than they are in the other three scenarios. Therefore, the cost-sharing contract can promote the level of green efforts in the home appliance supply chain. Finally, Figure 7 shows that within a reasonable cost-sharing ratio, Model C is higher than Model M when the cost-sharing ratio is greater than 0.079. In Figures 5, 8, Model M is higher than Model C. This suggests that in the two decision models that consider the impact of consumer subsidy on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making and the impact of the cost-sharing contract on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making, consumer subsidy has a more significant impact on the total profit of the supply chain and the level of retailer’s marketing publicity efforts than it does on the cost-sharing contract; and the cost-sharing contract has a more significant impact on the level of the manufacturer’s technological innovation efforts than it does on consumer subsidy.

FIGURE 5
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 5. Impact of cost-sharing ratio on the total profit of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain.

FIGURE 6
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 6. Impact of cost-sharing ratio on the profit of the home appliance manufacturer.

FIGURE 7
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 7. Impact of cost-sharing ratio on the level of technological innovation efforts.

FIGURE 8
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 8. Impact of cost-sharing ratio on the level of marketing publicity efforts.

5.3 Impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference β and green marketing sensitivity γ

It can be seen from Figures 9A, B that in Model D, Model M, Model C, and Model U, with an increase of consumers’ green intelligence preference, the technology innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers and the marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers increase accordingly. At the same time, it can be seen from Figures 10A, B that in Model D, Model M, Model C, and Model U, technology innovation efforts and marketing publicity efforts show the same trend of change with the increase of consumers’ green marketing sensitivity. That is, consumers’ green intelligence preference and consumers’ green marketing sensitivity produce spillover benefits, which benefit all enterprises in the home appliance supply chain. Therefore, as consumers increasingly favor green intelligent home appliance products produced by home appliance manufacturers, the market demand gradually increases, and home appliance retailers also increase their marketing publicity efforts to attract more consumers and obtain higher profits. Similarly, as consumers become more sensitive to the marketing publicity of home appliance retailers, the market demand gradually increases, and home appliance manufacturers become more active in improving the innovation level of green intelligent home appliance products to meet consumer green intelligent demands, thereby increasing profits. Corollary 6 is verified.

FIGURE 9
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 9. Impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference on the level of technological innovation efforts and marketing publicity efforts. (A) Impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference on the level of technological innovation efforts. (B) Impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference on the level of marketing publicity efforts.

FIGURE 10
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 10. Impact of consumers’ green marketing sensitivity on the level of technological innovation efforts and marketing publicity efforts. (A) Impact of consumers’ green marketing sensitivity on the level of technological innovation efforts. (B) Impact of consumers’ green marketing sensitivity on the level of marketing publicity efforts.

6 Conclusion

This article starts from the perspective of technological innovation and marketing publicity of the green intelligent home appliances supply chain, and it uses the Stackelberg game method to conduct research. With and without consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract, a three-level supply chain model comprising home appliance manufacturers, retailers, and consumers is constructed to study technological innovation and marketing publicity decisions within the supply chain. The study discusses the impact of consumers’ green intelligent preference, consumers’ green marketing sensitivity, and consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract on the optimal decision-making of supply chain members.

The results of the model analysis show that: (1) the increase in consumers’ green intelligent preference and consumers’ green marketing sensitivity produces positive spillover effects and promotes the improvement of home appliance manufacturers’ technological innovation efforts and retailers’ marketing publicity efforts. Sun and Yu (2018) and Sharm and Jain (2021) have also confirmed that consumer’s green preference has a positive impact on manufacturers’ green efforts of manufacturers. (2) Consumer subsidy has an incentive effect on the home appliance supply chain. Specifically, consumer subsidy can effectively increase not only the level of technological innovation efforts of home appliance manufacturers and total profit of the supply chain (Long et al., 2022; Pan et al., 2023) but also the level of marketing publicity efforts of home appliance retailers (Yuan et al., 2022). (3) When home appliance retailers adopt cost-sharing contract to help home appliance manufacturers reduce the cost pressure of technological innovation inputs, a reasonable cost-sharing ratio promotes both parties in the supply chain to participate in green activities, stimulate the enthusiasm of supply chain enterprises to increase technological innovation (Qin et al., 2021) and marketing publicity (Sharma and Jain, 2021) investment, increase the total profit of the supply chain, promote the green intelligent development of the home appliance industry, and achieve the coordinated development of economy and environment. However, when the cost-sharing ratio is very high, the operating costs of home appliance retailers are very high, and the enthusiasm for participating in coordination is frustrated, which reduces the overall benefit of the supply chain. Therefore, a reasonable cost-sharing ratio should be formulated to achieve the optimal decision-making effect of the supply chain. (4) When consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract coexist, a reasonable consumer subsidy amount and cost-sharing contract have a better impact on the total profit of the home appliance supply chain, the level of the manufacturer’s technological innovation efforts, and the level of the retailer’s marketing publicity efforts than they do in the other three scenarios. In addition, in the two decision models that consider the impact of consumer subsidy on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making and the impact of cost-sharing contract on green intelligent home appliance supply chain decision-making, consumer subsidy has a more significant impact on the total profit of the supply chain and the level of retailer’s marketing publicity efforts than does cost-sharing contract; and cost sharing contract has a more significant impact on the level of manufacturer’s technological innovation efforts than does consumer subsidy.

Based on the aforementioned research conclusions, the following management enlightenment is put forward, providing a broader reference for the green intelligent development of China’s home appliance industry. First, the government should increase policy support and provide subsidies to consumers who buy green intelligent home appliances, so as to help home appliance enterprises to improve their return on investments, shorten the economic return cycle, and expand their market scale, thereby raising the enthusiasm of home appliance enterprises in technological innovation and marketing publicity, and thus promoting the green intelligent development of the home appliance industry. Second, for home appliance enterprises, promoting the production and sales of green intelligent home appliances requires the joint efforts of home appliance manufacturers and home appliance retailers. While home appliance manufacturers carry out green technological innovations, home appliance retailers are required to attract more consumers through marketing publicity. On this basis, the introduction of the cost-sharing contract into the home appliance supply chain and a reasonable cost-sharing ratio will further enhance the earnings of enterprises in the home appliance supply chain. Therefore, home appliance enterprises should strengthen the cooperation with each other, further integrate internal resources, and take the initiative to meet market demand to achieve a win–win situation. Finally, the government and home appliance enterprises should actively promote green intelligent home appliances to consumers, cultivate consumers’ green intelligent preferences, and jointly create a strong atmosphere for the pursuit of green and low-carbon development in the whole society so that the concept of green and intelligent sustainable development gets deeply rooted in people’s hearts and minds, which can in turn promote an increase in the benefits of the home appliance supply chain and the continuous improvement of the quality of the ecological environment.

Limitations and future prospects resulting from this study: first, this study deals with optimal decision-making of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain under consumer subsidy policy, without involving the government to provide a certain proportion of the subsidies to home appliance manufacturers and retailers. In future research, it can explore how to achieve a win–win cooperation among all parties in the green intelligent home appliance supply chain while providing government subsidies to home appliance manufacturers and retailers, further improving the innovation level of green intelligent home appliance products, thus proposing a better government subsidy program. Second, this study uses a linear function to estimate the market demand of green intelligent home appliances. However, the market demand is affected by many factors, which makes it difficult to predict the demand. We can further consider the optimal decision-making problem of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain under the condition of uncertain demand. Finally, this study does not consider the risk aversion of home appliance manufacturers’ technological and retailers’ marketing publicity investment activities. In the future, the influence of variables such as the investment risk aversion preference of home appliance enterprises on the green intelligent effort and income of the green intelligent home appliance supply chain can be considered, making the research more detailed and in-depth.

Data availability statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary Material; further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author contributions

CC: conceptualization, methodology, manuscript writing–original draft, formal analysis, and funding acquisition. QL: conceptualization, software, and manuscript writing–original draft. QY: software and manuscript writing–review and editing. SL: manuscript writing–review and editing. HZ: funding acquisition, supervision, and manuscript writing–review and editing. XG: manuscript writing–review and editing.

Funding

The author(s) declare that financial support was received for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. This research was funded by the Shandong Soft Science Research Program General Project, grant number 2020RKE28013; the Qingdao Social Science Planning Research Project, grant number QDSKL21101039; and the Annual Routine Project of Dongying Social Science Planning, grant number DYSK (2022) No. 69.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the reviewers and the editor-in-charge for their valuable time on the article. The authors are grateful to all the foundations that supported them.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, editors, and reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Alejandre, C., Akizu-Gardoki, O., and Lizunda, E. (2022). Optimum operational lifespan of household appliances considering manufacturing and use stage improvements via life cycle assessment. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 32, 52–65. doi:10.1016/j.spc.2022.04.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bian, J. S., Zhang, G. Q., and Zhou, G. H. (2020). Manufacturer vs. Consumer subsidy with green technology investment and environmental concern. Eur. J. Operational Res. 287 (3), 832–843. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2020.05.014

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cao, Y., Xun, J. Y., Li, Q. S., Tan, Y., Zeng, M., Wang, L., et al. (2020). A rare case report of pituicytoma with biphasic pattern and admixed with scattered Herring bodies. Operation Res. Manag. Sci. 29, 108–118. doi:10.1186/s12957-020-01889-6

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chakraborty, T., Chauhan, S. S., and Ouhimmou, M. (2019). Cost-sharing mechanism for product quality improvement in a supply chain under competition. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 208, 566–587. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2018.12.015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Deng, Y. J. (2021). Under the “carbon neutral”. HFCs becomes key Emiss. Reduct. home Appl. industry. China Appl. 07, 22–23.

Google Scholar

Fan, J. C., Fu, H., Hong, D. J., and Wan, N. N. (2023). The research on the quality cost sharing contract in the retailer-led supply chain based on product liability. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 31 (05), 187–197. doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2020.1493

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ghosh, D., and Shah, J. (2015). Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 164, 319–329. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.11.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Guo, Y. T., and Zheng, G. (2019). How do firms upgrade capabilities for systemic catch-up in the open innovation context? A multiple-case study of three leading home appliance companies in China. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 144, 36–48. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2019.04.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hong, I. H., Chiu, A. S. F., and Gandajaya, L. (2021). Impact of subsidy policies on green products with consideration of consumer behaviors: subsidy for firms or consumers? Resour. Conservation Recycl. 173, 105669. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2021.105669

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, A. G. (2021). China’s goal of achieving carbon peak by 2030 and its main approaches. J. Beijing Univ. Technol. Soc. Sci. Ed. 21 (03), 1–15. doi:10.12120/bjutskxb202103001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, H. Q., Ge, Z. H., and Chen, L. H. (2020). Research on cost sharing strategy of retailer-dominated united innovation under competing supply chain. J. Industrial Technol. Econ. 39, 3–10. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1004-910X.2020.04.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, Y. X., Jiao, L. M., Qi, X., Li, J., and Jin, L. (2023). Interpretation of the standard, carbon neutralization technology-technical specification for evaluation of low carbon operation of intelligent household appliances-part 7: range hoods. China Stand. 03, 156–159. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1002-5944.2023.03.029

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Huang, J., Leng, M. M., Liang, L. P., and Liu, J. (2013). Promoting electric automobiles: supply chain analysis under a government’s subsidy incentive scheme. IIE Trans. 45, 826–844. doi:10.1080/0740817X.2012.763003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jafari, H. (2023). Energy storage by improving energy-efficiency of electricity home appliances under governmental supporting policies: a game-theoretic approach. J. Energy storage 63, 106972. doi:10.1016/j.est.2023.106972

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Khosroshahi, H., Dimitrov, S., and Hejazi, S. R. (2021). Pricing, greening, and transparency decisions considering the impact of government subsidies and CSR behavior in supply chain decisions. J. Retail. Consumer Serv. 60, 102485. doi:10.1016/j.jretconser.2021.102485

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lei, M. Y., Cai, W. J., Liu, W. L., and Wang, C. (2022). The heterogeneity in energy consumption patterns and home appliance purchasing preferences across urban households in China. Energy 253, 124079. doi:10.1016/j.energy.2022.124079

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, J. Z., Zhou, Y. P., Yu, D. K., and Liu, C. L. (2020). Consumers’ purchase intention of new energy vehicles: do product-life-cycle policy portfolios matter? Sustainability 12 (5), 1177. doi:10.3390/su12051711

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, K. P., and Wang, L. (2023). Optimal electric vehicle subsidy and pricing decisions with consideration of EV anxiety and EV preference in green and non-green consumers. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 170, 103010. doi:10.1016/j.tre.2022.103010

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, X. H., Shao, J. P., and Sun, Y. A. (2021). Research on the Stimulation of green and low-carbon product consumption market vitality: an evolutionary game based on green household appliances. Ecol. Econ. 37, 27–34.

Google Scholar

Li, Y. B., and Pan, T. (2019). Research on performance evaluation of dual-channel collaborative marketing of home appliances retail enterprises. Sci. Technol. Dev. 15, 637–643. doi:10.11842/chips.2019.06.013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lin, Q., and Liu, M. W. (2022). Green supply chain decision-making considering government subsidy and enterprise cost-sharing. Industrial Eng. J. 25, 29–38. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1007-7375.2022.06.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, P. (2021). Pricing rules of green supply chain considering big data information inputs and cost-sharing model. Soft Computing-A Fusion Found. Methodol. Appl. 25, 8515–8531. doi:10.1007/s00500-021-05779-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Long, Q. Q., Tao, X. Y., Chen, Y. T., Chen, Y. N., Xu, l., Zhang, S. Z., et al. (2022). Exploring combined effects of dominance structure, green sensitivity, and green preference on manufacturing closed-loop supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 251, 108537. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2022.108537

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lou, G. X., Qiu, Y. H., and Xia, H. Y. (2020). Green supply chain coordination considering R&D efforts and marketing investment. Industrial Eng. Manag. 25, 131–139. doi:10.19495/j.cnki.1007-5429.2020.04.016

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lou, W. D., and Ma, J. H. (2018). Complexity of sales effort and carbon emission reduction effort in a two-parallel household appliance supply chain model. Appl. Math. Model. 64, 398–425. doi:10.1016/j.apm.2018.07.042

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lv, T., and Huang, Y. N. (2021). Demand-induced innovation: evidence from the Chinese household appliance industry. Bus. Manag. J. 43, 25–43. doi:10.19616/j.cnki.bmj.2021.07.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ma, N. N., Gao, R., Wang, X. B., and Li, P. (2020). Green supply chain analysis under cost sharing contract with uncertain information based on confidence level. Soft Computing-A fusion Found. Methodol. Appl. 24, 2617–2635. doi:10.1007/s00500-019-03801-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ma, W. M., and Zhao, Z. (2013). How does government replacement-subsidy influence the closed-loop supply chain with different grades of products. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 21, 113–117. doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2013.03.017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nie, H. G., Zhao, T., Lu, H. Y., and Huang, S. P. (2021). Evaluation of the efficiency of Chinese energy-saving household appliance subsidy policy: an economic benefit perspective. Energy Policy 149, 112059. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2020.112059

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pan, J. T., Wang, D. P., and Tian, Y. (2023). Research on dual-channel green supply chain decision-making considering fairness concerns under government subsidies. J. Syst. Sci. Math. Sci., 1–20. doi:10.12341/jssms22808

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Qin, Q., Jiang, M. T., Xie, J. M., and He, Y. (2021). Game analysis of environmental cost allocation in green supply chain under fairness preference. Energy Rep. 09, 6014–6022. doi:10.1016/j.egyr.2021.09.020

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sharma, A., and Jain, D. (2021). Game-theoretic analysis of green supply chain under cost sharing contract with fairness concerns. Int. Game Theory Rev. 23, 2050017. doi:10.1142/S0219198920500176

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shen, G. L., Jin, H. Y., Yang, J., and Li, C. G. (2012). Experience-marketing based downstream SCM of household appliance enterprises. Logist. Technol. 31, 332–335. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1005-152X.2012.09.106

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Song, H. F., Chu, H. R., Yue, H. D., and Chen, Y. H. (2022). Green supply chain coordination with substitutable products under cost sharing contract. Procedia Comput. Sci. 199, 1112–1119. doi:10.1016/j.procs.2022.01.141

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Song, Y., Li, Z. R., and Zhang, M. (2019). Comparison of subsidy and taxation policies for promoting green product consumption from the perspective of heterogeneity. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 29, 59–65. doi:10.12062/cpre.20190312

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sun, D., Yu, Y. M., Chen, N., Li, S. M., and Fu, T. (2018). Determination of optimal government subsidy policy in green product market. Chin. J. Manag. 15, 118–122. doi:10.13702/j.1000-0607.170179

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sun, H. X., and Zhong, Y. (2023). Carbon emission reduction and green marketing decisions in a two-echelon low-carbon supply chain considering fairness concern. J. Bus. Industrial Mark. 38, 905–929. doi:10.1108/JBIM-02-2021-0090

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sun, J. H., and Zhang, H. B. (2020). A research on collaborative innovation cooperation strategy of green supply chain. Industrial Eng. J. 23, 53–60+92. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1007-7375.2020.04.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tong, W. (2020). Optimization and collaboration of carbon emission reduction and promotion of appliance based on cap-and-trade mechanism and consumers’ low-carbon preference. Beijing: Beijing Jiaotong University. doi:10.26944/d.cnki.gbfju.2020.003837

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, H., and Wang, C. C. (2023). Agricultural manufacturers’ carbon abatement oriented to government subsidy and sales efforts. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2, 1–29. doi:10.1007/s10668-022-02886-3

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, T. T., and Wang, D. P. (2020). Dynamic coordination strategy of cooperation on carbon emission reduction and low carbon propaganda in supply chain under government subsidy. Operations Res. Manag. Sci. 29, 52–61. doi:10.12005/orms.2020.0200

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xing, P., Zhou, C. P., and Li, C. J. (2023). Innovation effort strategy of green supply chain considering government subsidies. Comput. Integr. Manuf. Syst. 28, 1–31. Available at: . http://kns.cnki.net/kcms/detail/11.5946.TP.20220803.1843.006.html.

Google Scholar

Xu, G. N., Chen, H. R., Wu, X. L., and Zhou, C. (2020). Game analysis on green cost-sharing between competing supply chains. J. Syst. Eng. 35, 244–256. doi:10.13383/j.cnki.jse.2020.02.010

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, J., and Duan, Y. R. (2022). Pricing and greenness investment for green products with government subsidies: when to apply blockchain technology? Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 51, 101108. doi:10.1016/j.elerap.2021.101108

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. F., and He, Y. Y. (2022). Blockchain application in modern logistics information sharing: a review and case study analysis. Prod. Plan. Control, 1–15. doi:10.1080/09537287.2022.2058997

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. F., Lin, Z. R., Li, X., Shang, C. J., and Shen, Q. (2022a). Multi-objective robust optimisation model for MDVRPLS in refined oil distribution. Int. J. Prod. Res. 60 (22), 6772–6792. doi:10.1080/00207543.2021.1887534

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. F., Liu, W. Z., and Yu, L. A. (2022b). Trajectory prediction for heterogeneous traffic-agents using knowledge correction data-driven model. Inf. Sci. 608, 375–391. doi:10.1016/j.ins.2022.06.073

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. F., Wang, C. L., and Zhou, P. (2021). GVRP considered oil-gas recovery in refined oil distribution: from an environmental perspective. Int. J. Prod. Res. 235, 108078. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108078

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. F., and Wen, Z. F. (2023). Dynamic pickup and delivery problem with transshipments and LIFO constraints. Comput. Industrial Eng. 175, 10083. doi:10.1016/j.cie.2022.108835

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xue, J., Gong, R. F., Zhao, L. J., Ji, X. Q., and Xu, Y. (2019). A green supply-chain decision model for energy-saving products that accounts for government subsidies. J. Sustain. 11, 2209. doi:10.3390/su11082209

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yan, J. (2010). Research on green technological innovation of electronic appliance manufactures based on green purchasing. Sci. Manag. Res. 28, 102–105. doi:10.3969/J.ISSN.1004-115X.2010.05.023

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yang, S., and Zhao, D. T. (2015). Do subsidies work better in low-income than in high-income families? Survey on domestic energy-efficient and renewable energy equipment purchase in China. J. Clean. Prod. 108, 841–851. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.07.022

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yenipazarli, A. (2017). To collaborate or not to collaborate: prompting upstream eco-efficient innovation in a supply chain. Eur. J. Operational Res. 260, 571–587. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2016.12.035

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yi, Y. Y., and Li, J. X. (2018a). Cost-sharing contracts for energy saving and emissions reduction of a supply chain under the conditions of government subsidies and a carbon tax. Sustainability 10, 895. doi:10.3390/su10030895

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yi, Y. Y., and Li, J. X. (2018b). The effect of governmental policies of carbon taxes and energy-saving subsidies on enterprise decisions in a two-echelon supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 181, 675–691. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.01.188

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yu, H. (2021). In the home appliance industry, "carbon neutrality" has a long way and a tight time. China Appl. 07, 14–16.

Google Scholar

Yu, S., Hou, Q., and Sun, J. Y. (2020). Investment game model analysis of emission-reduction technology based on cost sharing and coordination under cost subsidy policy. Sustainability 12, 2203–2329. doi:10.3390/su12062203

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yu, X. H., Li, M., and Ye, Z. X. (2021). Analysis of the impact of energy-saving subsidies on dual-channel low-carbon supply chain decisions based on cooperative game. Fuzzy Syst. Math. 35, 153–166.

Google Scholar

Yuan, S. J., Li, J., and Su, X. (2022). Impact of government subsidy strategies on supply chains considering carbon emission reduction and marketing efforts. J. Sustain. 14, 3111. doi:10.3390/su14053111

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhao, L. X., and Wang, L. L. (2018). Development and prospect of carbon emission reduction policies in consumption field research. Sci. Technol. Manag. Res. 38, 239–246. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1000-7695.2018.03.036

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: “dual carbon” goal, consumer subsidy policy, cost-sharing contract, green intelligent home appliance supply chain, green efforts, Stackelberg game

Citation: Che C, Li Q, Yin Q, Li S, Zheng H and Geng X (2023) Research on technological innovation and marketing publicity decision of green intelligent home appliance supply chain considering consumer subsidy and cost-sharing contract. Front. Energy Res. 11:1259566. doi: 10.3389/fenrg.2023.1259566

Received: 16 July 2023; Accepted: 02 October 2023;
Published: 25 October 2023.

Edited by:

Michael Carbajales-Dale, Clemson University, United States

Reviewed by:

Li Li, Peng Zhen Li, China
Li Gaoguang, Beijing International Studies University, China
Dexiang Zhang, Qingdao University, China
Yifeng Wang, Suqian College, China

Copyright © 2023 Che, Li, Yin, Li, Zheng and Geng. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Qing Li, czIyMDgwMDA0QHMudXBjLmVkdS5jbg==

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.