Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Aquac., 11 September 2023
Sec. Society, Value Chains, Governance and Development

Governance challenges for Indonesian pond aquaculture: a case study of milkfish production in Gresik

  • 1Social Science Department, Leibniz Centre for Tropical Marine Research (ZMT), Bremen, Germany
  • 2Agrie Conservation, Gresik, Indonesia
  • 3Center for Life Ethics, University of Bonn, Bonn, Germany
  • 4Jacobs University Bremen, Bremen, Germany

Introduction: An important blind spot in current aquaculture governance research and practice is recognizing the high dependency of the sector on commons (i.e., shared resources), and their interconnectivity with other sectors such as agriculture. This is particularly evident in Indonesia where there is general lack of social and governance research on aquaculture. The purpose of this study is to: (1) identify the commons that need to be governed in pond aquaculture systems, and (2) identify the arising governance challenges from those commons and potential solutions.

Methods: We apply Elinor Ostrom’s Socio-Ecological Systems Framework (SESF) to identify variables influencing collective action through semi-structuredinterviews with relevant key informant actors in a milkfish aquaculture village in Gresik, Indonesia. Our case study approach allows for a rich description through qualitative data to understand system interactions. We interviewed 22 stakeholders including regional and local government officials, fish farmers (owners and workers), patrons and local academics.

Results and discussion: Our findings indicate five governance challenges influencing collective action: (1) limited access to capital and dependence on patrons, (2) lack of govern institutions, (3) continued government program failure, (4) lack of community leadership, and (5) lack of motivation and incentives to collectively act. These imply that governance policies may be more successful if monitoring mechanisms are applied to ensure that government funding is more precisely targeted at improving the livelihoods of traditional fish farmers. Furthermore, attempts to support social capital, network structures, and improve trust-reciprocity among relevant stakeholders (i.e., farmers, extension officers, private business actors) in the form of capacity building is likely more effective than other monetary incentives or the enforcement of top-down rules that don’t fit local needs.

1 Introduction

Indonesia’s aquaculture sector dates back to at least the 15th century, and is often typified by the Tambak (pond) cultivation technique. Tambak aquaculture relies on traditional brackish-water pond and canal systems to produce shrimp, milkfish, and other finfish (Troell, 2009; Henriksson et al., 2017; Partelow et al., 2018). Over the last two decades, expansion and intensification of the sector has made Indonesia into the second largest producer of aquaculture products in the world after China (FAO, 2022). The sector, however, is highly dependent on shared environmental resources or environmental commons (Partelow et al., 2021). The current challenge is that investment in production growth is outpacing the ability of institutions at all levels of governance to respond with effective rules and norms to address sustainability concerns such as environmental integrity, or livelihood and food security (Hishamunda et al., 2014; Bush et al., 2019). Another challenge is that effective governance solutions very likely need to be adapted to fit local contexts (Epstein et al., 2015), so that the implementation of widespread policy programs can be more effective when they include pilot or initiation phases that account for understanding local needs and building capacities to ensure the program properly engages with communities (Belton and Little, 2011; Rimmer et al., 2013; Partelow et al., 2018).

Common pool resources are characterized by excludability challenges and a high degree of subtractability, meaning it is difficult for an undefined group of actors to share a resource (e.g., fish) without problems of overuse (e.g., overfishing). Commons can create complex multi-user conflicts that result in over-extraction or resource collapse if rules and norms (i.e., institutions) for governance are not properly established (Agrawal, 2003; Partelow et al., 2021). Elinor Ostrom’s research on cooperative approaches (collective action) to commons governance has shown, however, that solving commons problems is possible under the right social and ecological conditions where rules and norms for governance fit local contexts (Ostrom, 1990). Collective action theory has emerged from this work to claim that high collective action is needed to maintain the commons and that with sufficient levels of collective action commons stakeholders can internalize externalities and prevent the over-use (Ostrom, 1990). Under the right conditions, collective action is made easier. Many variables have been shown to be influential on collective action (i.e., determining the conditions) including the size of the resource system, number of actors, resource unit mobility, leadership, norms, knowledge of the social-ecological system (SES), and dependence on the resource (Ostrom, 1990; Ostrom, 2007; Ostrom, 2009). The synthesized hypotheses of individual variables contributing to collective action are diverse and collated in the literature and in online databases such as SESMAD (https://sesmad.dartmouth.edu/theories/101). Based on an accumulated body of empirical commons research, Ostrom and colleagues developed a framework of potentially relevant variables for studying the commons that can be used to help scholars and practitioners diagnose governance problems in local contexts in order to improve understanding of the types of institutional solutions that might be most appropriate (Ostrom, 2007; Ostrom, 2009; McGinnis and Ostrom, 2014).

Ostrom’s Social-Ecological Systems Framework (SESF) (Ostrom, 2009) has been widely adopted and applied to understand environmental governance problems, but seldom in aquaculture systems despite their high dependency on commons (Partelow et al., 2021). The SESF provides a common vocabulary for social-ecological commons research, but there is no specific approach for applying it. The SESF has been applied to small-n (<5) qualitative case studies (Carrillo et al., 2019), large-n (>30) quantitative comparative research (MacNeil and Cinner, 2013), meta-analyses (Villamayor-Tomas et al., 2019), and as a deliberation tool (Partelow et al., 2019). The SESF describes the eight essential dimensions, or first-tier variables, of a social-ecological system (Table 1). Actors within and outside government operate within a Governance System characterized by formal and informal rules at one or more identifiable geographic scales. Resource Units inhabit and interact with a broader Resource System that is characterized by particular ecosystem types and biophysical processes, also at one or more geographic scales. External variables are also considered in Social, Economic, and Political Settings insofar as they influence Outcomes (McGinnis and Ostrom, 2014).

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Table 1 First and second-tier variables of the social-ecological systems framework.

The SESF has been applied to analyze many small-scale fisheries and irrigation case studies, both related to aquaculture. Furthermore, Johnson et al. (2019) provide a modified SESF for marine aquaculture, detailing the unique variables of mariculture systems for use in future studies. However, to our knowledge only two previous studies have applied the SESF to pond aquaculture systems – both examining cases on Lombok, Indonesia. The studies by Senff et al. (2018) and Partelow et al. (2018) showed that low system knowledge and low capacity building within policy programs to support fish farmers hindered production. Their findings indicated this was driven by the lack of problem awareness that maintenance of common canals was a driver of low water quality and insufficient quantity.

In this article, we aim to address this gap in SESF literature by examining the governance challenges of Indonesian milkfish farming using the SESF as a diagnostic tool in the Gresik district, the biggest milkfish producing region in Java, Indonesia, where ongoing government programs seek to develop a sustainable aquaculture business system within the sector. Within this context, this study is guided by four research questions:

1. What are the important aquaculture commons in Pangkah Wetan, Gresik?

2. What are the SES characteristics of traditional pond aquaculture in Pangkah Wetan, Gresik?

3. What are important SES variables hindering and/or enabling collective action to govern aquaculture commons?

4. What are the main governance challenges for traditional pond aquaculture in Pangkah Wetan, Gresik?

2 Material and methods

2.1 Study site

This case study is located in Pangkah Wetan village in Gresik, a district within the East Java Province of Indonesia. Gresik district is one of the leading producers of milkfish from coastal pond aquaculture in Indonesia (currently the second highest in national production after South Sulawesi). Gresik produces approximately 98,000 tons of milkfish per year, nearly triple the amount compared to other districts in the East Java Province (based on an interview with Dinas Perikanan Gresik). In Gresik, milkfish has become not only an economically, but also culturally important food source for communities, creating interdependent drivers of production. Every year before Eid al-Fitr, the regional government organizes a huge traditional market for milkfish for three consecutive days. The markets do not only provide fresh fish, but there is also a competition for the biggest milkfish cultured during the year. Pangkah Wetan village was selected due to the importance of milkfish production to the local economy, livelihoods, national food and nutrition security, and as a local protein source for preventing stunting in childhood development. Milkfish are produced in traditional aquaculture ponds, and the total production area has expanded substantially over the last decade to cover a total area of 2,465.49 Hectares (ha) of ponds throughout the whole village, covering 77.3% of the total village area (Figure 1). The village is located in the delta of the biggest river in Java, Bengawan Solo. Milkfish (Chanos chanos) production is commonly practiced as monoculture or polyculture with Vanemei shrimp (Litopenaeus vannamei). In April 2022, MMAF (Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries) also started the initial Kampung Bandeng project in the study area. This government program focuses on intensification and expansion strategies to secure national fish production by launching a national priority program for 2021-2024 called Corporate Farming (Kampung Perikanan Budidaya) stated in Indonesia Marine Affairs and Fisheries Ministrial Regulation number 47/2021. This program aims to encourage a sustainable aquaculture business system to secure national food security by continuous and scheduled production, and engages different processes along the value chain including the hatchery, fish feed factory, quality assurance, supporting infrastructure and facilities, cold storage, ice and packaging industries. However, the lack of socio-ecological and governance information on milkfish production hinders effective management decisions. This research provides basic information about the governance challenges of milkfish farming in Gresik and policy recommendation for the related stakeholders.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1 Location of Kampung Bandeng (Milkfish Aquaculture Village) in Pangkah Wetan (red star), Gresik. The spatial areas referenced in the paper are colored respectively. The Gresik district is located in east Java, Indonesia.

2.2 Data collection and analysis

Data collection was conducted from October-December 2021 using face-to-face semi-structured interviews. Purposive sampling was applied to identify key informant actors based on their contribution to solving collective action problems including government officials, community leaders, local university lecturers, and fish farmers (Table 2). Verbal prior informed consent was received from all interviewees, and this consent was recorded, which included background information on ourselves and purpose of the study. All participants asked were willing. Then, a snowball sampling approach was utilized to find additional relevant informants, especially among fish farmers. Snowball sampling (see Parker et al., 2019) was started with a casual talk with the fish farmers in the warung (food stall) located near the ponds. These were not considered formal interviews but provided substantive information about who to talk to. Semi-structured interviews with key informants inquired about variables of the SESF (Ostrom, 2009; McGinnis and Ostrom, 2014; Partelow, 2018) – which provided qualitative data to both characterize the social-ecological system functionality and diagnose commons governance challenges. This research followed existing general guidelines for applying the framework (Nagel and Partelow, 2022). As such, data were collected using a diagnostic approach guided by the updated version of the SESF (McGinnis and Ostrom, 2014). It is important to acknowledge, however, that although we pursued a diagnostic and saturation-based approach, our informants and interviewees may not reflect the full spectrum of actors involved in the pond systems, including the often hidden role of women in the value chain, other marginalized members or other value chain actors that shape incentives, prices or policies but whom may not be located in Gresik.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

Table 2 Respondents list.

Interview data were transcribed into text and analyzed using content analysis (Stemler, 2001) to identify the key SESF variables characterizing the types of commons that exist in the system, as well as the factors influencing whether or not stakeholders are engaged in collective action to govern their aquaculture commons in Gresik. Interview data were organized and coded using the open-source coding software Taguette (https://www.taguette.org/). Data were coded to variables of the SESF, and could be coded to multiple variables. Data were collated into nested thematic areas, where more specific codes could be created and assigned to data enabling a full picture to emerge in a way that linked to the theory in the framework (i.e., variable nestedness and connectivity) while remaining flexible to context. Nested coding structures enable the aggregation and separation of themes based on similarities and differences across text segments. The SESF is a practical tool for coding qualitative data because it provides the core concepts and relationships central to the analysis of commons, but because it provides a nested structure for identifying social-ecological interactions that become easier to identify with coding software. Using the description of each second-tier variable in the case, we further examined the data through the lens of collective action theory, where each variable in the framework has its own literature in relation to its role in collective action, particularly in the coastal small-scale fisheries literature. Data were coded as being high/low or strong/weak in the final assessments in relation to the hypothesis for collective action for each variable. If not explicitly coded in relation to high/low, for example, the interpretation of the influence of the variable was guided by the literature on the hypothesized role of the variable. For example, leadership has shown to be a critically important factor in collective action because good leadership can organize groups, motivate information sharing and help build social capital for self-organizing working together on commons issues (Lobo et al., 2016; Crona et al., 2017). Given the lack of available literature on pond aquaculture collective action problems, for some variables we proposed new hypotheses regarding their relationship to collective action. This gives more explanation about the variable’s role and its impact on the governance outcomes related to collective action in the local context. Secondary data were also collected. However, there is so little research and knowledge about the topic and the case area specifically, that hardly any documents were found from the regional government, university archives or published research in English or Bahasa in peer-reviewed journals. There is even a lack production data despite governments efforts to pursue production as the key indicator. In summary, this study is both a diagnostic qualitative assessment and an exploratory, in that there is little prior knowledge to base it on, making it one of first few studies on commons and aquaculture governance in the country.

3 Results

3.1 Characterizing pond aquaculture in Gresik as a social-ecological system

3.1.1 Resource systems

Pangkah Wetan is the center of milkfish farming in Indonesia aquaculture (RS1), which is largely split across the main inland area, and a nearby sedimentation island. Ponds located inland are adjacent to people’s houses and are traversed by fishery irrigation canals. Meanwhile, the ponds on the sedimentation island are bordered by the Bengawan Solo river as the ecological boundary (RS2). Most inland ponds are not surrounded by mangroves or other plant species, while the dikes of the island-based ponds are dominated by Avicennia spp (Api-api in local language). In several locations on the island, new land clearing for more intensive fish farming has been observed, with the consequence of clearing large mangrove areas. The total pond area in Pangkah Wetan covers 50% of the total pond area in Gresik with a total of 2,003.09 Ha (RS3). Since 2000, fish farmers started to use fish feed as an additional source of food for the cultured species, and now approximately 90% of fish farmers use fish feed which no longer makes it a traditional farming practice, but rather semi-intensive. Local communities recognized it as a “traditional plus” farming system.

The total area of each pond is estimated between 3-7 Ha and each fish farmer owns a pond area between 3 to 50 Ha (RS4). In Pangkah Wetan, farmers normally conduct three farming cycles in two years with an average production of 8-10 tons per farming cycle dominated by a polyculture system between milkfish, tilapia, and Vanamei shrimp (RS5). Pangkah Wetan area has two main seasons. The wet season is from October-April, and dry season from May-September. Water is available all year around from the Bengawan Solo river (RS 6). In general, pond aquaculture in Pangkah Wetan Village is located in two separate areas: (1) inland and (2) on a sedimented island in the Solo Delta Estuary (RS9). During the wet season, fish farmers with island ponds experience annual floods, potentially losing their harvest due to broken dikes followed by fish escapes (RS7). Ponds in the sedimentation islands require larger operational funds than inland ponds because they require boats to transport people, feed and harvest fish (RS9).

3.1.2 Resource units

Brackish water pond aquaculture is centered around milkfish (Chanos chanos) production. There are three types of farming systems: (1) milkfish monoculture, (2) milkfish and Vannamei shrimp polyculture, and (3) milkfish, Vannamei shrimp, and tilapia polyculture. However, milkfish input and production remains the largest. Due to the large pond size, milkfish fries have to reach 10-15cm long in the nursery pond before moving in to the rearing pond for feeding. Most of the fry are produced in Central Java or Bali because of the high demand in Gresik (RU1). As the main commodity in Gresik, milkfish production contributes over one trillion rupiahs (68.8 million USD)/year) (RU4). Both monoculture and polyculture usually needs 1 packaged shoal of fry (5,000 individuals) per hectare of pond (RU5). For Vannamei shrimp, up to 10 packs of fry per hectare can be grown depending on the willingness and capital availability. Every year there are three peak times where market value for pond aquaculture products are highest, which are the dry season on the north coast of Java, Ramadhan/Eid Festival, and New Year’s Eve.

3.1.3 Actors

Pangkah wetan has a total of 601 fish farmers, 13 fish farmer groups (Pokdakan), one fish processing group (Poklasar) and one fish farmer association (A1). Fisheries field officers (Petugas Penyuluh Lapang/PPL) are assigned directly by the Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries, with one officer covering 1 sub-district. However, the area covered by one officer can be quite large, for example, the Ujung Pangkah sub-district consists of 11 villages. There are also other entities along the value chain such as private fish feed suppliers (GS2, A1) and fish buyers (Patrons) (A5). Trust and reciprocity occurs between fish farmers and patrons. Every patron supports around 50 fish farmers every farming cycle (A6). Most of the milkfish farmers in Pangkah Wetan village have been cultivating for generations, but cultivation practices make limited use of technology (A3). Until now, the use of technology is only limited to diesel fuel pumps that function as water pumps in and out of the pond and as an aerator (A9). Traditional plus milkfish farmers also understand that feed is not the only determinant of harvest success, but also water and soil. Soil needs to be managed (i.e., removed from the bottom of the ponds) after harvest to get better outcomes for the next harvesting cycles by removing fish waste (A7). Unfortunately, since the pond area is rented land, they must effectively utilize the pond during rental time, because this is the main source of income for ‘traditional plus’ (i.e., fed system) fish farmers (A8). The larger the pond, although more difficult to manage, yields a greater profit (A5). Based on the government documents and the interviews, the goals of each major actor are shown in Table 3.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

Table 3 Actors goal in each jurisdiction based on document analysis and interview analysis.

3.1.4 Governance system

Aquaculture in Gresik is under the authority of Department of Fisheries of Kabupaten Gresik at the regional level, Department of Marine and Fisheries at the provincial level, and the Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries nationally (GS1). At the time of this analysis, the Department of Fisheries has not published their new strategic plan (2021-2026), so insights here examine existing programs. There are four main focal areas within the department according to its organizational structure as of 2016: the aquaculture sector, capture fisheries sector, management and supervision of fisheries resources, and processing and marketing of fisheries product (GS3). For supporting technical issues, the Department of Fisheries has two Technical Unit Divisions (UPT- Unit Pelaksana Teknis) in the Gresik region, which are Fresh/Brackish water aquaculture unit and the Campurejo Fish Market.

For aquaculture, the Department of Fisheries was focused on land rights certification for fish farmers (GS4), development of fish cultivator diversification (A2), introduction of catfish and biofloc aquaculture (A9), independent fish feed movement, Vannamei demonstration plot, and fish farmer’s insurance facilities (A9). In Pangkah Wetan, all programs were carried out except the catfish introduction and biofloc for product diversification.

The Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries assigns field extension officers for fisheries in every sub-district (Kecamatan) in Indonesia with the functions of coaching, controlling, licensing, and sharing information related to all marine activities and fisheries (GS3). The field extension officer (Petugas Penyuluh Lapang- PPL) is responsible to the ministry but not to the regional Department of Fisheries. The regional government encourages the registration of aquaculture businesses to all cultivators but not many have registered their businesses (GS4). Therefore, monitoring and control functions can only be done for registered fish farmers (GS8). Traditional plus farming systems (i.e., fed systems) are well established in Pangkah Wetan, which means adding fish feed at the beginning of the cycle by almost all fish farmers. The use of unregistered drugs is understood to be prohibited, but according to the fish farmers, other registered drugs don’t work well (GS5). Every fish farmer has their own best practice for aquaculture based on previous experience, even though an aquaculture best practice guide (CBIB) has been provided by the government. Furthermore, for the general population, the government has aimed to increase public awareness about the importance of fish consumption (S5). For example, in campaigns such as the GEMARIKAN (Gemar Makan Ikan) providing annual and monthly programs in collaboration with community-based healthcare providers (sub district level) to reduce stunting in children.

In the farming community, there are four key social structures. The social structure is stratified based on control on property rights, capital, and labor that relate to power and influence. At the top of the social hierarchy are farm owners, followed by tenants and manager farmers in the middle, and farm workers at the bottom.

3.1.4.1 Farm owners

Are those who control the pond’s profits and management, either by using their own power or the labor of others, typically owning the land and using hired labor. Farm owners and pond workers have transactional relationships, some permanent. On average, owners invest between IDR rupiahs 6-10 million (400-650 USD) per hectare for milkfish farming.

3.1.4.2 Tenant farmers

Are those who have sufficient capital but do not own the land. To be able to control the profit, they rent ponds under contract agreements. Tenant farmers rely on sufficient capital in their pond business. For example, the capital required for a 12 hectare area for milkfish cultivation is IDR 400 million (26,500 USD) for one production cycle within seven months (Laksono et al., 2020).

3.1.4.3 Managers

Are farmers who have a lot of energy and skills, but do not have rights to farm profits, and do not have enough capital to rent. They work in other people’s ponds under profit-sharing agreements, also sharing production costs.

3.1.4.4 Pond workers (Pandega)

Are hired laborers in ponds. They do not have the capital to buy - let alone rent - so they depend entirely on being employed by owners and tenant farmers to work. On average, pond workers are paid IDR rupiah 2 million per month for feeding and securing the pond. During harvesting, some are paid extra for use of specific tools and techniques.

Pond owners/tenants with large pond sizes, normally employ workers (Pandega) for daily work including feeding, operating pumps, checking water quality, and securing ponds. The workers usually take a day off on Friday due to Friday Prayer in Muslim communities (GS5). Profit sharing between workers and pond owners/tenants can be between 10-25% of the total profit, or can also be in the form of a monthly salary system.

To carry out cultivation activities, a large amount of capital is needed. Fish feed is the largest expenditure in traditional plus systems. On the island-based systems, acquiring feed depends heavily on patrons (Juragan) to provide daily fish feed and as an eventual buyer for their harvest (GS2.1). There are five Patrons (Juragan) in Pangkah wetan area, and each Patron can handle more or less 50 fish farmers with harvest quantities up to 10 tons of fish per fish farmer. Feeding starts from the beginning of the growing phase, and when the fish weight between 200-300 grams, water pumps are activated every night for aeration (A7, A9). When it comes to harvest time, milkfish are caught with a net (krikit).

Government subsidies for fish fry or machinery for fish feed processing can be accessed by farming groups. The main farmer group recognized by the government is Pokdakan (Kelompok Pembudidaya Ikan- Fish Farmer Group) whose formation needs to be approved by the village chief (GS7). In Pangkah Wetan, group formation is based on the location of the pond. Especially for ponds located on islands, the groups are divided depending on the location of tributaries to make it easier to organize (GS6). For example, Pokdakan Kali Paloh, Pokdakan Kali Kunti, Pokdakan Kali Sumbalan, etc. The function of monitoring and sanctions by the government is carried out for large-scale or intensive cultivators such as Vannamei shrimp cultivation. In addition, the monitoring function is only carried out if there is a report from the community about irresponsible aquaculture activities (GS8).

3.1.5 Key interactions

There are two key types of investment in Gresik, (1) government investments (I5.1) and (2) farming practice investments (I5.2). The government - through the Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries - supports collective action among fish farmers through the creation of Pokdakan (Kelompok Pembudidaya Ikan/Fish Farmer Groups) to access government support (I5). For example, they can receive information on Indonesian good farming practices (CBIB), which refers to the FAO Technical Guidelines for Aquaculture Certification and Asean Good Aquaculture Practice (GAqp) (I2), receive fish seed and tools, or get social benefits for the fish ponds affected by the flood. The Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries has its own certification scheme for aquaculture practices called CBIB (Cara Budidaya Ikan Yang Baik) or Good Aquaculture Practice certification. CBIB is based on the FAO Good Farming Standard. Although in practice, subsidies given are often not utilized by the farmers for aquaculture improvements, but instead used for other purposes. For example, fish seed allocation for one group can only be used for one person due to the pond size and fish need in each pond. One group, in our findings, stated that the support only lasted for one farming cycle and the money from harvests was to reconstructed the road to access the ponds (I7). In many cases, groups sell the fish feed right away and distribute the money evenly to all farmers, rather than directly utilizing it to improve shared aquaculture resources. Another form of support is the natural feed makers and a package of starter materials because of the high prices of raw materials compared to factory made feed. There are no monitoring activities after the aid is delivered because most of it was in the grant scheme (I9). Fish farmers also form an association group at the village level to attract investments from companies operating around the area (I8). Based on the pond location the aquaculture commons dependencies in Gresik are shown in Table 2. For example, an important difference between island and inland ponds is that island areas have restricted access to formal monetary institutions although the government has provided several options for low interest loans. A common financial institution requires a land certificate as capital loan collateral. Due to its vulnerable location in the Bengawan Solo Delta, the milkfish ponds are exposed to the risk of annual floods. This drives the fish farmers to refuse formal financial support from banks because they would then have to give their land certificates as a requirement for the loan, which they perceive as too risky.

3.2 Aquaculture commons and drivers of collective action

3.2.1 Aquaculture commons in Gresik

Commons are the shared resources that aquaculture stakeholders use and rely on together, and need to govern together, in order to produce aquaculture products. Aquaculture systems in Gresik have numerous commons that create a need for collective action to provide and maintain the condition or availability of the shared commons (Table 4).

TABLE 4
www.frontiersin.org

Table 4 Aquaculture commons in island and inland pond systems.

3.2.2 Hindering and enabling conditions for collective action

From the perspective of the fish farmers, there are three main drivers to collectively govern milkfish aquaculture in Milkfish Village. They are to (1) increase productivity for their livelihood, (2) become independent fish farmers, and (3) receive assistance from the government. These motivations arise to get the desired outcomes to be able to farm sustainably, have better access to the market, reduce dependence on the patrons (intermediary traders), and access suitable government aid.

Fish farmers that operate in inland areas have more access to financial support and the aquaculture value chain, including financial support from formal institution (Bank and others), best market prices, infrastructure (i.e., roads and electricity) and better fish feed and seed. Island-based fish farmers have limited access to above mentioned goods. Additionally, island farms are prone to flood. Thus, island-based fish farmers are more willingly to form a group to work together with the purpose of maintaining public goods, for example, the road and dikes to mitigate their deterioration due to raining and floods.

Compared to the island-based fish farmers, inland fish farmers have more public goods including appropriate road access for fish feed delivery and harvest, although less capital and collective action needed to maintain roads and electricity infrastructure. For inland farmers, good environmental conditions supporting milkfish aquaculture and low risk from natural hazards reduce incentives for farmers for collaborating compared to island-based fish farmers.

Linking the above results to collective action theory, we discuss the interactions between key variables in relation to their influence to collective action (Table 5). Despite the collective efforts taken between the government and fish farmers to increase productivity, challenges for governance still remain including who is eligible for funding, how to better implement the program, how to monitor the program, and who is responsible for specific tasks. It has also been observed that there is a strong interaction between the pond location, fish farmers’ location, and heterogeneity of the actors increasing transaction cost (deliberation and collective choice rules). Low monitoring of group performance by the government, lack of government staff, and weak leadership by the group leader are supporting reasons for reduced willingness for collective action. A full list of 2nd and 3rd tier SES framework variables and their relation to collective action is provided in Table 6.

TABLE 5
www.frontiersin.org

Table 5 Drivers of collective action in milkfish aquaculture and the desired outcomes.

TABLE 6
www.frontiersin.org

Table 6 SES second and third-tier variables related to collective action problem in Gresik Milkfish Village.

Over the years, ponds were no longer owned by local fish farmers. Due to urbanization, next generation inheritance and higher education in the third generation of the farming society shows low interest in farming activity. More and more ponds were sold to external inhabitants, left to be rented by hired fish farmers. A typical situation is that a hired fish farmer (with minimum capital) practices traditional aquaculture (non-fed), while pond owners or tenants (more capital) prefer a traditional plus (feeding) techniques. The traditional technique requires less capital and less effort or time investment. Pond tenants only interested in fish production and not taking care of the pond, like strengthening the dike or maintenance of public infrastructure even if it can affect their production. Since they live far away from the pond, and can only be there once in a while, it makes it difficult to collectively work in a group. This can cause a problem when the ponds are located in the riverbank as the first embankment for other ponds. If not strengthened through maintenance, risk from floods is higher that the surrounding ponds will be destroyed causing harvest losses.

Therefore, from the perspective of resource user, location clearly influences motivation for collective action. Island-based farmers are more willing to form a group due to the risk of the annual flood. Especially those which are located on the riverside. Every year, high tide is predicted to happen at night and noon. This natural phenomenon can cause the brake of the embankment leading to harvest losses. Therefore, collective action is needed to protect their pond from the loss and to have good access to the ponds by collectively maintaining the road. Contrarily, fish farmers in the inland area feel no urgency to form a group. Just recently, fish farmers in the inland area formed a group because of the need to receive government aid which requires road and electricity access as the main requirements for the recipient of the aid. External factors from the government’s intervention (providing a financial incentive to cooperate) have proven to enable collective action. This confirms that these two variables - location and government investment - are very influential in motivating primarily pond farmers to work together. However, it is unclear if collective action would continue if or when government aid programs stop.

In Gresik, it is still perceived by many fish farmers that they are facing a decline in productivity due to the behavior of pond farmers who are not environmentally friendly (e.g., using feed without water and post-harvest soil treatment) even though the government has provided knowledge facilities on how to do this as a ‘best aquaculture practice’. Such government efforts include a district fisheries government extension officer who works in the area daily with farmers to discuss challenges. The officer is tasked with introducing central government programs, organizing fish farmers group, informing farmers how to receive aid, but rarely provides inputs on farming technique interventions. The reasons for these perceived declines among farmers despite extension officer efforts are diverse. For example, fish farmers are heterogeneous actors, with major differences in property rights, operational rules, and also different levels of knowledge. Milkfish farming activities in Gresik have been carried out on the island and on the mainland for a long time. However, group formation for island-based fish farmers started around 5-7 years ago. During that time, there has only been minimum monitoring and control from the government. Low monitoring or control causes a low level of trust and reciprocity, which have been shown to increase the likelihood that people will contribute to maintaining the quality and quantity of resources (Marshall, 2004). Building trust and establishing norms of reciprocity can therefore help overcome other norms (e.g., lack of trust, individualism) to help break barriers to collective action (Graham et al., 2019). Patrons (GS2), in contrast, have leveraged their position of shaping and creating norms well. They have established a group consisting of 50 fish farmers and are typically able to encourage participatory monitoring carried out among fellow members in the patron group due to high connectivity and trust reciprocity (A6).

In this case study, we found that the location of the pond (RS9) affects the availability of human-constructed facilities (RS4) to incentivize self-organization between island-based fish farmers to take care of the road access to their pond. Not only the road access, but challenges in doing milkfish farming in island areas also involves the risk of harvest loss during high tide in the wet season because of the broken dikes located on the Bengawan Solo river. However, some fish farmers face difficulties in bringing people together to solve the challenges. This is due to several factors, including changes in the behavior (A3) of the cultivation community from traditional to traditional plus feed (GS5). This also has an impact on investment activities (I5) in terms of energy, time, and cost. Conversely, a group consisting of the farmers using the same aquaculture techniques and having similar socio-economic status, for example among traditional fish farmers, tend to cooperate better. Homogenous characteristics among farmers seems to increase the likelihood of collective action, whereas in contract, diverse groups face more barriers due to higher transaction costs in understanding or identifying with each other.

In addition, changes in land ownership (GS3) that were previously owned by pond farmers, are now often leased out. This plays an important role because tenants usually do not intervene in pond repairs such as strengthening embankments or repairing roads to ponds. Usually, the tenants live far from the pond (A4) so it is difficult to meet, where the only communication options are calling or texting via cellular phones for pond management. With traditional pond farming, due to lower input requirements, farmers can still carry out other professions as shrimp collectors or fishing because they have more available time compared to pond farmers with feed. Therefore, the desire to work together to improve shared public goods is lacking due to less dependence on the system. Leadership at the community level (A5) has proven to be able to encourage groups to work together. Unfortunately, not many leaders have the ability to persuade others. Some leaders use their power to access government programs for themselves. Others choose to ignore the problems only to avoid conflict. Better leadership skills at the community level can be seen within the fish farmer association, where they have built a network (I8) with the private company operating in the area to access funding for maintaining the bridge to access their ponds.

Fish farmers in general understand various social-ecological system interactions, but the knowledge they have has not proven to be enough to enable collective action to reduce their risks and increase income or sustainability outcomes. Farmers typically understand variables of the biophysical environment required for milkfish cultivation such as coping with sudden changes in weather, predictability of the upcoming high tide (RS7), use of appropriate feed, how to do best aquaculture practices, pond waste management needs, local politics, market choices, as well as the patrons have available capital to support farming activities and market access.

In order to increase knowledge, fish farmer group formation aims to facilitate guidance and information/knowledge sharing by the government. This aims to encourage fish farmers to solve problems as a group and to generate added value in their products so they are able to improve their livelihood and welfare (interview with Gresik Fisheries Agency, 2021). However, this target is unlikely to be achieved in the near future in Gresik milkfish village because the perceived goal of the aquaculture community is to produce as much fish as possible rather than cooperate to solve joint problems. Despite the training and lots of assistance with seeds of various species to cultivate, milkfish pond farmers have rather fixed perspectives that milkfish farming is the only reasonable option due to the biophysical condition of the ponds, market, characteristics of the milkfish itself, knowledge of milkfish culturing, and capital availability (A8). As a result, fish farmer groups (Pokdakan) typically work together with the intention of fulfilling government requirements to get assistance (Zulkarnain, 2020), and are not formed as an institution that can accommodate all the interests of group members. In addition, high dependence on the system doesn’t influence fish farmers to act beyond economic motives. Low monitoring provides minimal feedback to inform policy changes.

4 Discussion

4.1 Five governance challenges facing Gresik milkfish aquaculture

Gresik milkfish aquaculture relies on a range of social and environmental commons, however the extent to which local actors are collectively acting to manage their shared resources is mixed. The five main factors influencing collective action have been identified with the application of the SES Framework. The five governance challenges are: (1) limited access to capital and dependence on patrons, (2) lack of govern institutions governing the common, (3) continued government program failure, (4) lack of community leadership skill and knowledge exchange, and (5) lack of motivation and incentives to collectively act. In the following sections, we explore the details of each.

4.1.1 Limited access to capital and dependence on patrons

Financing aquaculture production is a major issue for fish farmers in Gresik. The challenge is exacerbated by the general trends of decreasing farm productivity, and the limited scope of government subsidy programs, which are often only enough to support one farmer in a given group. Farmers therefore remain highly dependent on wealthy patrons. Patron-client relationships remain central to aquaculture value chains, therefore including them in formal governance strategies has the potential to harness their influence of farmer behavior within policy design and implementation (Drury O’Neill et al., 2019). Literature has shown that fishers may be particularly vulnerable to exploitation because they are often in debt to buyers (patrons) and have no access to collective-choice arenas (decision-making processes) shaping their working conditions (Basurto et al., 2020). Patron-client relations in fisheries and aquaculture might have different institutional arrangements, however. Patrons in Gresik have been establishing positive relationships with fish farmers for years with minimal conflict. Although the interaction between fish farmers and patron needs to be studied in the future, there is a potential of collaboration between actors through informal governance.

4.1.2 Lack of institutions amongst heterogeneous farmers to govern shared aquaculture commons

The consistent lack of appropriate operational rules amongst fish farmer groups in Gresik is exacerbated by inadequate law enforcement at the government level. Additionally, the demand for economic returns and high actor diversity were identified to create a system exhibiting high transaction costs, making deliberation, cooperation, and shared rule-making difficult (Ostrom, 2009). A large degree of heterogeneity was identified between fish farmers, such as dependence on aquaculture as either a full-time or part time livelihood and socio-economic attributes. This leads to low levels of interaction and little sense of community (Acheson, 2006). Similar findings in other cases have shown that homogenous and smaller group are likely to cooperate more effectively (Agrawal, 2001). The tambak resource systems in Gresik are heterogeneous as well, for example island ponds face higher sedimentation and transportation challenges which may require different institutional solutions than inland ponds. Identifying farms and farmers with similar characteristics, and then forming groups around them, may be a potential option.

4.1.3 Continued government program failure

Government programs to develop pond aquaculture as a sustainable business in Gresik can be characterized by a consistent lack of success, notably the lack of aquaculture business registration which is a requirement to access additional government support, and limited uptake of Indonesian good aquaculture practice (CBIB) protocols. Relatedly, the lack of registered aquaculture business degrades the capacity of government monitoring and control of the farmer group development, namely the extent to which government assistance provides solutions for fish farmers. Low monitoring can lead to lower levels of trust and reciprocity between government and resource user actors due to perceived lack to control over the behavior of others. In contrast, trusting relationships have been found to increase the likelihood that people will contribute to maintaining the quality and quantity of resources (Marshall, 2004). These issues are exacerbated by the lack of field officers for aquaculture in Gresik. Actors serving in these extension roles can fill an important bridging role between government and local fish farmers to improve uptake of government development programs (Thompson et al., 2006).

4.1.4 Lack of leadership skill at the community level

At the community level, fish farmers’ leadership skills have been observed to motivate the group members to participate in self-organizing activities for governing public goods (road access to pond) and private goods (broken dikes). These findings align with other literature suggesting that strong leadership has been relevant in motivating self-organization (Poteete et al., 2010; Basurto et al., 2013). In Gresik, leaders are chosen based on their experience and social status, which leads to differences in leadership qualities. When the period ends, the new leader does not necessarily have the same skills because there are no mechanisms for knowledge transfer or leadership training in the community.

4.1.5 Lack of motivation and incentives to collectively act

Knowledge of SES did not motivate fish farmers’ collective action in order to increase the added value or diversify products with the aim of increasing income. Although the fish farmers are aware that the productivity of the system is declining, their limited resources (money/pond size) (I5) reduce incentives for collective action. Existing research (Basurto and Ostrom, 2009) strongly indicate that the lack of knowledge about the resource prevents fishers from making a prediction about the dynamic of the system and thus affects their self-organized ability. Our findings that while fish farmers recognize SES problems, there may be a lack of knowledge regarding how these problems are shared resource problems requiring self-organization and cooperation. For example, while farmers may be aware of the impact of degrading water quality on production, they may not be recognizing how the upkeep of common waterways (i.e., irrigation canals) can contribute to water quality upkeep. Without appropriate understanding regarding how investing this money can improve shared aquaculture resources and long-term production outcomes, farmers will favor short-term financial incentives rather than long term investments in aquaculture. A lack of problem recognition reducing incentives for collective action is a challenge which has previously been documented in other cases of pond aquaculture in Indonesia (Partelow et al., 2018).

4.2 Policy recommendations

To summarize our findings, we here provide a brief summary of potential policy solutions to the most influential governance challenges hindering collective action in Gresik and suggested policy solution (Table 7). The following list can be used to reflect on policy program designs that can better address sustainability issues. Each problem is matched with potential policy solutions that may help improve success.

TABLE 7
www.frontiersin.org

Table 7 Main governance problems identified for milkfish aquaculture in Gresik. Suggested policy solutions to address each problem are provided.

Policy makers are encouraged to understand the aquaculture systems they aim to change through a social-ecological approach by getting feedback from extension officers and coordinating knowledge sharing activities among local to regional extension officers, universities and aquaculture stakeholders to synthesize challenges and potential improvements that can be used as inputs into revising policy. This means that better efforts can be made to consider a wider range of factors related to the sector to be regulated in order to ensure the most appropriate and sustainable management. Policy is a key lever of governance, and if governance aims to shape the behavior of actors in the system, then understanding the conditions that those actors operate in can inform the development of rules and norms that better address the hindering conditions for collective action (e.g., group diversity, low monitoring, location differences) while leveraging the enabling conditions (e.g., positive patron-client relations). Developing context appropriate rules and norms can directly guide the use, maintenance, and distribution of shared resources in aquaculture although such approaches to the sector to governance are rarely discussed (Partelow et al., 2021).

Science-based information can be used to support government programs. To do this, establishing collaboration between actors in Gresik aquaculture is a good starting point. Collaborative development and sharing of knowledge by multiple actors have been shown as an effective pre-condition for contextualizing policy design and improving science (Armitage et al., 2012). For example, partnerships with local universities who have been doing research in the area for years can help build relationships with local fish farmers. Training programs which increase knowledge capacity of farmers in regards to shared resource problem recognition can increase the incentives for farmers to collaborate to reduce shared risks. Collaboration and learning are a potential way for managers (regional agency) and scientists to engage (and not necessarily formally) with different types of knowledge and perspectives (Armitage et al., 2012). Even though no single blueprint exists for how to succeed by using collaborative approaches, emerging insights suggest that effective collaborative arrangement leverages several factors underlying collective action problems such as increasing the quantity and quality of communication to lower transaction costs and build trust (Bodin, 2017).

5 Conclusions

This study provides an initial assessment into aquaculture governance challenges in pond aquaculture systems through examining the case of Gresik, the largest pond production area for milkfish (Chanos chanos) in Indonesia. We have identified the commons the system depends on, and its emergent governance challenges in governing them effectively. We highlight five factors influencing governance and collective action, which ultimately drive production and farmer livelihood outcomes such as income: (1) limited access to capital and dependence on patrons, (2) lack of govern institutions, (3) continued government program failure, (4) lack of community leadership, and (5) lack of motivation and incentives to collectively act. Following these, this study draws three important conclusions. First, establishing partnerships among local stakeholders to improve communication and share knowledge, including with the local university, can help inform aquaculture governance fit to address local challenges and adjust policy program implementation in a way that works locally. Second, government investments may be more effective when they incentivize collective action when they avoid monetary incentives, but instead focus on improving leadership skills in the community. Third, the government programs - initiated through extension officers and regional inter-governmental partnerships - should consider co-producing knowledge with different actors to provide a baseline for monitoring mechanisms and to avoid program failures based on a lack of trust or knowledge of programs.

Data availability statement

The raw data supporting the conclusions of this article will be made available by the authors upon request, without undue reservation.

Ethics statement

The project within which this research was funded (COMPASS, BMBF) followed required ethical clearance procedures in its research packages and projects outlined by the funder and institutional mandates of the Leibniz Centre for Tropical Marine Research (ZMT). The authors state that good scientific practices were followed, and that the low risk of the study in obtaining interview data from prior informed consenting adults meets ethical clearnance standards outlined by the institute, funders and in Indonesia. The studies were conducted in accordance with the local legislation and institutional requirements. Verbal prior informed consent was obtained from all participants and recorded with audio. These meets local standards in this context for obtaining interviews in Indonesia and the host institute.

Author contributions

CR: Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal Analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing. SP: Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing. BN: Conceptualization, Supervision, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing.

Funding

The is research was funded by the German Ministry of Research and Education (BMBF) within the project COMPASS: Comparing Aquaculture System Sustainability, grant number 031B0785.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the aquaculture communities and interviewees in Gresik who gave their time and energy to participate in this study. We would also like to thank Adiska Octa Paramita, Achim Schlüter, Nurliah Buhari and Eva Anggraini for their inputs on the design and implementation of this research. The study was conducted in partnership with the University of Mataram and Bogor University.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

The author SP declared that they were an editorial board member of Frontiers, at the time of submission. This had no impact on the peer review process and the final decision.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Acheson J. M. (2006). Institutional failure in resource management. Annu. Rev. Anthropology 35, 117–134. doi: 10.1146/annurev.anthro.35.081705.123238

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Agrawal A. (2003). SUSTAINABLE GOVERNANCE OF COMMON-POOL RESOURCES : context, methods, and politics. Annu. Rev. Anthropol 32 (1), 243–262. doi: 10.1146/annurev.anthro.32.061002.093112

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Agrawal A. (2001). Common Property Institutions and Sustainable Governance of Resources. World Development 29(10), 1649–1672. doi: 10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00063-8

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Armitage D., de Loë R., Plummer R. (2012). Environmental governance and its implications for conservation practice. Conserv. Lett. 5 (4), 245–255. doi: 10.1111/j.1755-263X.2012.00238.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Basurto X., Bennett A., Lindkvist E., Schlüter M. (2020). Governing the commons beyond harvesting: An empirical illustration from fishing. PloS One 15 (4), 1–18. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0231575

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Basurto X., Gelcich S., Ostrom E. (2013). The social-ecological system framework as a knowledge classificatory system for benthic small-scale fisheries. Global Environ. Change 23 (6), 1366–1380. doi: 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.08.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Basurto X., Ostrom E. (2009). The Core Challenges of Moving Beyond Garrett Hardin. Journal of Natural Resources Policy Research 1(3), 255–259. doi: 10.1080/19390450903040447

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Belton B., Little D. C. (2011). Immanent and interventionist Inland Asian aquaculture development and its outcomes. Dev. Policy Rev. 29 (4), 459–484. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-7679.2011.00542.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bodin Ö. (2017). Collaborative environmental governance: Achieving collective action in social-ecological systems. Science 357 (6352), 1–8. doi: 10.1126/science.aan1114

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bush S., Belton B., Little D. C., Islam S. (2019). Inclusive environmental performance through ‘beyond-farm’ aquaculture governance. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain 41, 49–55. doi: 10.1016/j.cosust.2019.09.013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Carrillo I. I. C., Partelow S., Madrigal-Ballestero R., Schlüter A., Gutirrez-Montes I. (2019). Do responsible fishing areas work? Comparing collective action challenges in three small-scale fisheries in Costa Rica. Int. J. Commons 13 (1), 7–5=746. doi: 10.18352/ijc.923

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cinti A., Shaw W., Torre J. (2010). Insights from the users to improve fisheries performance: Fishers’ knowledge and attitudes on fisheries policies in Bahía de Kino, Gulf of California, Mexico. Mar. Policy 34 (6), 1322–1334. doi: 10.1016/j.marpol.2010.06.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Crona B., Gelcich S., Bodin Ö. (2017). The importance of interplay between leadership and social capital in shaping outcomes of rights-based fisheries governance. World Dev. 91, 70–83. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.10.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Di Gregorio M., Hagedorn K., Kirk M., Korf B., McCarthy N., Meinzen-Dick R. S., et al. (2008). Property rights, collective action, and poverty: The role of institutions for poverty reduction. CGIAR.

Google Scholar

DJPB. (2020). Renstra Dirjen Perikanan Budidaya 2020-2024.

Google Scholar

Drury O’Neill E., Crona B., Ferrer A. J. G., Pomeroy R. (2019). From typhoons to traders: The role of patron-client relations in mediating fishery responses to natural disasters. Environ. Res. Lett. 14 (4). doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/ab0b5

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Epstein G., Pittman J., Alexander S. M., Berdej S., Dyck T., Kreitmair U., et al. (2015). Institutional fit and the sustainability of social–ecological systems. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain 14, 34–40. doi: 10.1016/j.cosust.2015.03.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

FAO (2022). The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2022. Towards Blue Transformation (Rome: FAO). doi: 10.4060/cc0463en

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gould R. V. (1993). Collective action and network structure. American sociological review, 182–196.

Google Scholar

Graham S., Metcalf A. L., Gill N., Niemiec R., Moreno C., Bach T., et al. (2019). “Opportunities for better use of collective action theory in research and governance for invasive species management,” in Conservation Biology, vol. 33. (Blackwell Publishing Inc), 275–287. doi: 10.1111/cobi.13266

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Henriksson P. J. G., Tran N., Mohan C. V., Chan C. Y., Rodriguez U.-P., Suri S., et al. (2017). Indonesian aquaculture futures - Evaluating environmental and socioeconomic potentials and limitations. J. Clean Prod 162, 1482–1490. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.06.133

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hishamunda N., Ridler N., Martone E. (2014). Policy and governance in aquaculture: Lessons learned and way forward. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Technical Paper. (Rome: FAO), 577.

Google Scholar

Johnson T. R., Beard K., Brady D. C., Byron C. J., Cleaver C., Du K., et al. (2019). A social-ecological system framework for marine aquaculture research. Sustainability 11 (2522), 21. doi: 10.3390/su11092522

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

KKP (2020). Recana Strategies Kemeterian Kelautan dan Perikanan 2020-2024.

Google Scholar

Laksono S. A., Hakim R. R., Handajani H. (2020). Analisa Kelayakan Usaha Budidaya Ikan Bandeng (Chanos-chanos) di Desa Pangkah (Universitas Muhammaddiyah Malang). Available at: https://eprints.umm.ac.id/66965/2/NASKAH%20PUBLIKASI.pdf.

Google Scholar

Lobo I. D., Vélez M., Puerto S. (2016). Leadership, entrepreneurship and collective action: A case study from the Colombian Pacific region. Int. J. Commons 10 (2), 982–1012. doi: 10.18352/ijc.640

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

MacNeil A., Cinner J. E. (2013). Hierarchical livelihood outcomes among co-managed fisheries. Global Environ. Change 23 (6), 1393–1401. doi: 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.04.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Marshall G. R. (2004). Farmers cooperating in the commons? A study of collective action in salinity management. Ecological economics 51(3-4), 271–286.

Google Scholar

McGinnis M. D., Ostrom E. (2014). Social-ecological system framework: Initial changes and continuing challenges. Ecol. Soc. 19 (2). doi: 10.5751/ES-06387-190230

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nagel B., Partelow S. (2022). A methodological guide for applying the SES framework: A review of quantitative approaches. Ecol. Soc. 27 (4), 39. doi: 10.5751/ES-13493-270439

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ostrom E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press). doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511807763

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ostrom E. (2007). A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 104 (39), 15181–15187. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0702288104

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ostrom E. (2009). A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social-ecological systems. Science 325(5939), 419–422. doi: 10.1126/science.1172133

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Parker C., Scott S., Geddes A. (2019). Snowball Sampling (Sage Publications: Sage Research Methods). doi: 10.4135/9781526421036831710

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Partelow S. (2018). A review of the social-ecological systems framework: Applications, methods, modifications, and challenges. Ecol. Soc. 23 (4). doi: 10.5751/ES-10594-230436

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Partelow S., Fujitani M., Soundararajan V., Schlüter A. (2019). Transforming the social-ecological systems framework into a knowledge exchange and deliberation tool for cOmanagement. Ecol. Soc. 24 (1). doi: 10.5751/ES-10724-240115

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Partelow S., Schlüter A., O. Manlosa A., Nagel B., Octa Paramita A. (2021). “Governing aquaculture commons,” in Reviews in Aquaculture, vol. 14. (John Wiley and Sons Inc), 729–750. doi: 10.1111/raq.12622

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Partelow S., Senff P., Buhari N., Schlüter A. (2018). Operationalizing the social-ecological systems framework in pond aquaculture. Int. J. Commons 12 (1), 485–518. doi: 10.18352/ijc.834

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Poteete A., Janssen M. A., Ostrom E. (2010). WORKING TOGETHER: Collective action, the Commons and Multiple Methods in Practice. Princeton Universty Press.

Google Scholar

Putnam R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American community. Simon and schuster

Google Scholar

Rimmer M. A., Sugama K., Rakhmawati D., Rofiq R., Habgood R. H. (2013). A review and SWOT analysis of aquaculture development in Indonesia. Rev. Aquac 5 (4), 255–279. doi: 10.1111/raq.12017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Senff P., Partelow S., Indriana L. F., Buhari N., Kunzmann A. (2018). Improving pond aquaculture production on Lombok, Indonesia. Aquaculture 497, 64–73. doi: 10.1016/j.aquaculture.2018.07.027

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Stemler S. (2001). An overview of content analysis. Pract. Assessment Res. Eval. 7 (17). doi: 10.7275/z6fm-2e34

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Thompson P. M., Firoz Khan A. K. M., Sultana P. (2006). Comparison of aquaculture extension impacts in Bangladesh. Aquaculture Economics Manage. 10 (1), 15–31. doi: 10.1080/13657300500315786

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Troell M. (2009) Integrated marine and brackishwater aquaculture in tropical regions:research,implementation and prospects. Available at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/258187211.

Google Scholar

Villamayor-Tomas S., Oberlack C., Epstein G., Partelow S., Roggero M., Kellner E., et al. (2019). Using case study data to understand SES interactions: a model-centered meta-analysis of SES Framework applications. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustainability 44, 48–57. doi: 10.1016/j.cosust.2020.05.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zulkarnain M. H., Karneli O. (2020). Implementasi Program Bantuan Pakan Dan Benih Terhadap Kelompok Budidaya Ikan (Pokdakan). JIANA (Jurnal Ilmu Administrasi Negara). 18(2), 96–105.

Google Scholar

Keywords: aquaculture governance, milkfish pond, Kampung Bandeng, social-ecological system, Asia

Citation: Riany CF, Partelow S and Nagel B (2023) Governance challenges for Indonesian pond aquaculture: a case study of milkfish production in Gresik. Front. Aquac. 2:1254593. doi: 10.3389/faquc.2023.1254593

Received: 07 July 2023; Accepted: 22 August 2023;
Published: 11 September 2023.

Edited by:

Kristian Karlo Saguin, University of the Philippines Diliman, Philippines

Reviewed by:

Edison D. Macusi, Davao Oriental State University (DOrSU), Philippines
Stuart W. Bunting, Independent Researcher, Sudbury, United Kingdom

Copyright © 2023 Riany, Partelow and Nagel. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Stefan Partelow, stefan.partelow@uni-bonn.de

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.