Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Appl. Math. Stat., 01 December 2023
Sec. Mathematical Finance
This article is part of the Research Topic Horizons in Applied Mathematics and Statistics View all 4 articles

The implied views of bond traders on the spot equity market

  • 1Department of Mathematics and Statistics, Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX, United States
  • 2Department of Mathematics, University of California San Diego, La Jolla, CA, United States

This study delves into the temporal dynamics within the equity market through the lens of bond traders. Recognizing that the riskless interest rate fluctuates over time, we leverage the Black-Derman-Toy model to trace its temporal evolution. To gain insights from a bond trader's perspective, we focus on a specific type of bond: the zero-coupon bond. This paper introduces a pricing algorithm for this bond and presents a formula that can be used to ascertain its real value. By constructing an equation that juxtaposes the theoretical value of a zero-coupon bond with its actual value, we can deduce the risk-neutral probability. It is noteworthy that the risk-neutral probability correlates with variables like the instantaneous mean return, instantaneous volatility, and inherent upturn probability in the equity market. Examining these relationships enables us to discern the temporal shifts in these parameters. Our findings suggest that the mean starts at a negative value, eventually plateauing at a consistent level. The volatility, on the other hand, initially has a minimal positive value, peaks swiftly, and then stabilizes. Lastly, the upturn probability is initially significantly high, plunges rapidly, and ultimately reaches equilibrium.

1 Introduction

Our study begins with an exploration of the market, as characterized by the SPDR S&P 500 ETF Trust (SPY). We develop a binomial tree for this market, in line with the conventions of previous work on binomial option pricing [1], ensuring the preservation of the market's mean and natural upturn probability. Following this foundational understanding, we transition into the evaluation of the term structure of interest rates (TSIR).

A common approach within the TSIR involves drawing conclusions based on treasury data and subsequent hypotheses. It is noteworthy that standard TSIR models frequently assign risk-neutral probabilities as follows: (p~,q~)=(12,12). However, this assumption is challenged by real-world data from the financial market, as highlighted by Hu et al. [1] and Shreve [2]. A possible avenue then emerges: to decipher the risk-neutral dynamics, even if only through a largely theoretical model, that align with bond prices. By leveraging such probabilities, models such as Hu et al. [1] can offer a valuation of derivatives on the TSIR.

In the context of this paper, our meticulous preservation of the equity market's mean, natural upturn probability, and volatility in our bond valuation opens up an avenue to discern bond traders' perspective on these parameters. This perspective is in contrast to the implied probabilities perceived by option traders, a nuance previously overlooked by traditional TSIR models. The crux of this paper, therefore, is to explore the nuances of the equity market through the lens of bond traders. This research is organized into three pivotal sections.

First, we elucidate the Black-Derman-Toy (BDT) model, tracing its historical significance in mathematical finance. Our emphasis remains primarily on the discrete incarnation of the BDT model, which offers insights into the market's temporal riskless interest rate transformations. For the computation of the associated BDT model coefficients, we harness the prior 252 days of U.S. 10-year treasury bond interest rate data, which are processed using MATLAB.

Next, our study pivots to the vantage point of bond traders, introducing the concept of the zero-coupon bond. Through a binomial model, we endeavor to derive a systematic pricing algorithm for this bond; this is followed by a method that can be used to ascertain its real value. By establishing a relationship between the theoretical and real values of the zero-coupon bond, we identify the risk-neutral probability. Given that a simplistic risk-neutral probability assumption of (p~,q~)=(12,12) might yield unrealistic outcomes,1 we expand this concept to derive parameters such as the instantaneous mean return, volatility, and natural upturn probability. This is further bolstered with simulated data, which are used to interpret these parameters over time.

In our conclusion, we discuss insights into the evolutionary trajectory of the equity market over the span of our study.

2 The BDT model

2.1 The history of the BDT model

The BDT model, named after its creators, Black, Derman, and Toy, originated within Goldman Sachs during the 1980s. Initially conceived for the firm's internal utilization, its significance garnered broader recognition following its publication in the Financial Analysts Journal in 1990 [3]. Derman offers a first-hand account of the model's evolution in his 2004 memoir [4].

Within the realm of mathematical finance, the BDT model is highly regarded as a short-rate model that is instrumental in pricing bond options, swaptions, and various other interest rate derivatives. It is different from other finance models in that it is a one-factor model, meaning that the short rate serves as the sole stochastic determinant for the future trajectory of all interest rates. The BDT model pioneered the amalgamation of the mean-reverting behavior of the short rate with the log-normal distribution, a paradigm shift underscored by Buetow et al. [5]. Its applicability and relevance persist today, as noted by Fabozzi [6].

2.2 Theoretical support

In Shreve [2], one can find a presentation of the BDT model in the discrete case. In the present paper, we will also consider this form of the BDT model. Because the interest rate in the BDT model changes over time, we can consider the interest rate as a risky asset ℝ and suppose that at every point in time, the interest rate will strictly go up or not. Additionally, we suppose that the interval between two adjacent points in time is Δ = 1/252.2 Now, we define the interest rate return3 in the period [, (n + 1)Δ]:

r(n+1)Δ=R(n+1)Δ-RnΔRnΔ.    (1)

For every n in the range 0, ⋯   , N − 14, the interest rate return can be described as follows:

r(n+1)Δ={uΔwith probability p,dΔwith probability 1-p,    (2)

where the sequence of returns, denoted by r5 for n = 1, ⋯   , N, comprises identically distributed binary random variables.

Furthermore, let the expected return of r(n+1)Δ be represented as 𝔼[r(n+1)Δ]=μ(n+1)Δrate=μrateΔ, where μrate stands for the instantaneous mean return of the interest rate. Therefore, the relationship becomes

μ(n+1)Δrate=μrateΔ=puΔ+(1-p)dΔ,

which implies that

μrate=pu+(1-p)d.    (3)

Now, let the variance of r(n+1)Δ be represented as follows:

𝕍[r(n+1)Δ]=(σ(n+1)Δrate)2=(σrate)2Δ,

where (σrate)2 is the instantaneous variance of the interest rate. By introducing

νΔrate=σrateΔ,

we can obtain

(σ(n+1)Δrate)2=(σrate)2Δ=(νΔrate)2Δ2.    (4)

Given that,

𝕍[r(n+1)Δ]=𝔼[r(n+1)Δ]2-𝔼2[r(n+1)Δ].    (5)

By combining (4) and (5), we can derive

(σ(n+1)Δrate)2=(νΔrate)2Δ2=pu2Δ2+(1-p)d2Δ2                            -[puΔ+(1-p)dΔ]2    (6)
                            =pu2Δ2+(1-p)d2Δ2-p2u2Δ2-2p(1-p)udΔ2                            -(1-p)2d2Δ2    (7)
                            =p(1-p)u2Δ2+p(1-p)d2Δ2-2p(1-p)udΔ2    (8)
                            =p(1-p)(u-d)2Δ2.    (9)

Since u > d, νΔrate=p(1-p)(u-d).

By combining the expressions for μrate and νΔrate in (3) and (9), we obtain the following system of equations:

{μrate=pu+(1-p)d,νΔrate=p(1-p)(u-d).    (10)

If we treat μrate and νΔrate as constants and u and d as unknown variables, the solution of (10) should be

{u=μrate+1-ppνΔrate,d=μrate-p1-pνΔrate.    (11)

Now, by combining (1), (2), and (11), we obtain

R(n+1)Δ={RnΔ(1+uΔ) with probability p,RnΔ(1+dΔ) with probability 1-p,    (12)
={RnΔ(1+μrateΔ+1-ppνΔrateΔ) with probability p,RnΔ(1+μrateΔ-p1-pνΔrateΔ) with probability 1-p,    (13)

for n = 0, ⋯   , N − 1.

Next, considering the format of the BDT model on page 172 in Shreve [2],

Rn(ω1ωn)=anbn#H(ω1ωn),

where

• ωi for i − 1, ⋯   , n represents the resulting change in the interest rate. ωi can be either H or T. If ωi = H, the interest rate increases; if ωi = T, the interest rate does not increase.

#H1⋯ωn) counts the occurrences of H in the given n periods, representing the number of times the interest rate increases.

an and bn are coefficients used to calibrate the model.

Following the form of an and bn in Shreve [2], we assume that an=R0/c1n and bn = c2, where R0 is the interest rate at time 0, while c1 and c2 are constants. By combining this assumption with (13), we deduce the following:

c2c1=1+μrateΔ+1-ppνΔrateΔ,    (14)
1c1=1+μrateΔ-p1-pνΔrateΔ.    (15)

From relations (14) and (15), we can write

an=R0(1+μrateΔ-p1-pνΔrateΔ)n,    (16)
bn=1+μrateΔ+1-ppνΔrateΔ1+μrateΔ-p1-pνΔrateΔ.    (17)

The coefficients in (16) and (17) represent our revised BDT model for this study.

2.3 Simulation of coefficients for the BDT model

In this study, we utilize the interest rate of the U.S. 10-year treasury bond6 as our primary data source. The reference starting date is set to June 16, 2023, which means that R0 is set to 0.0377. Our analysis will utilize 252 days7 of historical data to compute the values of an and bn.

Employing MATLAB for our computations, we derived the values for c1 and c2 as c1 = 1.0236 and c2 = 1.0464, respectively. Figure 1 contrasts the observed market value of the interest rate with the predicted values deduced from the BDT model, covering the period from June 15, 2022 to June 16, 2023.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1. Comparison of market and BDT model interest rates.

Thus, for dates starting from June 16, 2023, our BDT model predicts the interest rates Rn1⋯ωn) as follows:

Rn(ω1ωn)=0.03771.0236n·1.0464#H(ω1ωn).

3 Introduction to zero-coupon bonds

The core objective of this paper is to explore the temporal dynamics of the equity market as perceived by bond traders. To that end, this section delves into the relevant details concerning zero-coupon bonds. Subsequent subsections will first detail a pricing algorithm specific to zero-coupon bonds. Following that, we will outline a methodology for deducing the implied value of the inherent upturn probability, the instantaneous mean return, and the instantaneous volatility pertinent to the equity market.

3.1 Zero-coupon bond pricing algorithm

A zero-coupon bond can be viewed as a specific type of European contingent claim8 (ECC). This characterization is due to its unique features: it has a predetermined maturity date, cannot be traded prior to its maturity, and guarantees a payoff of $1 upon maturity regardless of external conditions.

Let us denote the price of the zero-coupon bond at time t, with the bond reaching maturity at time T, as B(t, T). It is a given that B(T, T) ≡ 1. To price this bond, we adopt a traditional binary model, as described by Shreve [2]. Using the notation established earlier,

B(nΔ,T)=11+RnΔΔ{p~B[(n+1)Δ,T](u)+(1-p~)B[(n+1)Δ,T](d)},    (18)

where

• Δ represents the time interval, which is set to 1/252.

B(nΔ, T) indicates the bond price at time , with a maturity T = .

B[(n + 1)Δ, T](u) and B[(n + 1)Δ, T](d) are potential bond prices at time (n + 1)Δ, with the former being greater than B(nΔ, T) and the latter being less than or equal to B(nΔ, T).

R is the interest rate at , derived using the BDT model.

p~ is the risk-neutral upturn probability in the equity market.

For ease of representation, let us denote the bond notations B(nΔ, T), B[(n + 1)Δ, T](u), and B[(n + 1)Δ, T](d) as B, B(n+1)Δ(u), and B(n+1)Δ(d), respectively. The instantaneous mean return in the equity market will be labeled as μe.m. and its variance will be labeled as σe.m.2. Thus, (νΔ)e.m.=σe.m./Δ.

Given the bond's ECC nature, it should be backed by an underlying risky asset 𝕊. To ascertain the risk-neutral probabilities, one could design a risk-free portfolio:

PnΔ=DSnΔ-BnΔ,    (19)

where

P is the riskless portfolio value at .

S is the underlying asset's price at .

D defines the ratio of shares between the zero-coupon bond and the risky asset 𝕊, ensuring a riskless portfolio.

Given the riskless nature of Equation (19), it inherently satisfies

P(n+1)Δ(u)=P(n+1)Δ(d).

This leads to

DS(n+1)Δ(u)-B(n+1)Δ(u)=DS(n+1)Δ(d)-B(n+1)Δ(d).    (20)

Equation (20) implies the relationship

D=B(n+1)Δ(u)-B(n+1)Δ(d)S(n+1)Δ(u)-S(n+1)Δ(d).    (21)

Given the inherent risk of asset 𝕊 and recalling the formulation from (13), we have

S(n+1)Δ(u)=SnΔ(1+μe.m.Δ+1-ppνΔe.m.Δ),    (22)
S(n+1)Δ(d)=SnΔ(1+μe.m.Δ-p1-pνΔe.m.Δ).    (23)

Substituting (22) and (23) into (21) yields

D=B(n+1)Δ(u)-B(n+1)Δ(d)SnΔσe.m.Δp(1-p).    (24)

From Equations (18), (19), and (24), it follows that

BnΔ=11+RnΔΔ[(pθe.m.p(1p)Δ)B(n+1)Δ(u)            +(1p+θe.m.p(1p)Δ)B(n+1)Δ(d)],    (25)

where θe.m. = (μe.m.R)/σe.m.. From Equation (25), the risk-neutral upturn probability is given by

p~=p-θe.m.p(1-p)Δ.    (26)

With Equations (18) and (26) and the condition B(NΔ, T) = B(T, T) ≡ 1, we derive the complete pricing algorithm for the zero-coupon bond.

3.2 Linking zero-coupon bonds to the equity market

Our objective in this subsection is to deduce the implied value of the natural upturn probability, instantaneous mean return, and instantaneous volatility for the equity market by analyzing them through the lens of a zero-coupon bond.

The expectation is that the zero-coupon bond's price, as calculated using the algorithm detailed in the previous subsection, aligns with the bond market's price.9 To ascertain the price of the zero-coupon bond within the bond market, we refer to Hull [7] and utilize the following formula:

B(t,T;market value)=exp[-(T-t)Y(t,T)],    (27)

where

t represents the present time.

T denotes the maturity date of the specific zero-coupon bond (for robustness in our findings, we will be considering bonds with maturities spanning from two months to thirty years).

Y(t, T) is the yield to maturity.

The algorithm we developed in the preceding subsection provides us with a means to calculate the theoretical price of the zero-coupon bond. This can be represented as follows:

B(t,T,μe.m.,p,σe.m.;theoretical value).    (28)

Our next step entails equating Equations (27) and (28). Doing this will reveal the implied values for the natural upturn probability, instantaneous mean return, and instantaneous volatility, all of which are vital metrics for understanding the equity market when it is viewed through the prism of a zero-coupon bond.

3.3 Estimation of parameters for the equity market

To deduce the values of the parameters μe.m., p, and σe.m., we will utilize the data associated with the SPY from June 15, 2022 to June 16, 2023. This duration encompasses precisely 252 business days. Our data source will be Yahoo Finance.

The rationale behind selecting these data is multifaceted. Bond prices often mirror the broader economic landscape. Given that the SPY can act as a representative index for the economy, it is plausible to infer that SPY data offer insight not only into the economy's state but also into the nuances of the equity market. Our preliminary estimates for μe.m., p, and σe.m. are 8.0037 × 10−4, 0.4821, and 0.0126, respectively.

As mentioned in the preceding subsection, our task is to equate (27) and (28). By doing this, we can ascertain the value of the risk-neutral upturn probability p~. By leveraging Equation (26) and concentrating on the parameters p, μe.m., and σe.m., we find that any two of the parameters can be utilized to express the third. Specifically,

μe.m.=σe.m.(p-p~)p(1-p)Δ+RnΔ,    (29)
σe.m.=(μe.m.-RnΔ)p(1-p)Δp-p~,    (30)
         p=(2p~+Δθe.m.2)-Δθe.m.2[Δθe.m.2+4p~(1-p~)]2(1+Δθe.m.2).    (31)

Since our start date is set to June 16, 2023, we will let R be the riskless interest rate on June 16, 2023, which is 0.0377. Now, by employing Equations (29), (30), and (31), we can produce graphs reflecting the implied values for μe.m., σe.m., and p, which are shown in Figures 24, respectively.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 2. Temporal analysis of the implied return in the equity market.

From these graphs, we can observe the following trends:

• In Figure 2, the implied return rises sharply from approximately -0.11. It then starts to climb at a decelerated pace and eventually stabilizes around 0.025.

Figure 3 shows that the volatility initially surges, reaching its zenith at 0.04 by the 10th year. Following this peak, there is a slight decline, and it settles near 0.035.

• As for Figure 4, the implied upturn probability experiences a sharp dip from its starting point of roughly 0.83. This decline slows over time, with the probability ultimately converging to approximately 0.48.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 3. Temporal analysis of the implied volatility in the equity market.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 4. Temporal analysis of the implied upturn probability in the equity market.

4 Conclusion

In this study, we delved into the temporal evolution of the SPY index within the equity market through the lens of bond traders. Our focus has been on deducing the implied values of the instantaneous mean return, instantaneous volatility, and natural upturn probability over time. Our primary conclusions can be summarized as follows:

• The implied value of the instantaneous mean return is initially negative. However, with the passage of time, this value experiences an increase, eventually reaching a stable point.

• As for the implied value of the instantaneous volatility, it initially has a marginal positive value. Shortly thereafter, it peaks before possibly descending to a steady state.

• The implied upturn probability starts at a notably high value but experiences a pronounced decline as time progresses. It too attains stability over time.

Data availability statement

Publicly available datasets were analyzed in this study. This data can be found here: Yahoo Finance (https://finance.yahoo.com/) and U.S. Department of the Treasury website (https://home.treasury.gov/).

Author contributions

YHe: Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Resources, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing. YHu: Methodology, Resources, Software, Writing – review & editing. SR: Conceptualization, Methodology, Project administration, Supervision, Visualization, Writing – review & editing, Resources.

Funding

The author(s) declare that no financial support was received for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher's note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Footnotes

1. ^An in-depth discussion on this topic can be found in Hu et al. [1].

2. ^This is based on the standard notion that a typical year comprises 252 business days, making the time interval 1/252, with the units being years.

3. ^R signifies the value of the interest rate at time . Similar notation conventions apply elsewhere.

4. ^In our study, we utilize data spanning 252 days to estimate each parameter and refine our BDT model. Consequently, N = 1/Δ = 252.

5. ^When r(n+1)Δ equals , the interest rate exhibits a clear upward trajectory. However, when r(n+1)Δ is equal to , the interest rate does not strictly ascend. By design, u > d should hold true.

6. ^Related data are available on the U.S. Department of the Treasury website.

7. ^Given that the commencement date is June 16, 2023, the data from the prior 252 days span June 15, 2022 to June 16, 2023. We have opted for a 252-day dataset because it offers a suitable sample size, ensuring that besides market fluctuations, other objective factors remain relatively stable within the year.

8. ^We consider a zero-coupon bond to be analogous to a European contingent claim due to the intrinsic differences between the European and American trading styles. Specifically, European-style trading restricts activity until the terminal time, while American-style trading permits trading at any given moment.

9. ^This price should accurately represent the zero-coupon bond's real-world value.

References

1. Hu Y, Lindquist WB, Shrivani A, Fabozzi FJ. Market complete option valuation using a Jarrow-Rudd pricing tree with skewness and kurtosis. J Econ Dynam Control. (2022) 137:104345. doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2022.104345

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

2. Shreve SE. Stochastic Calculus for Finance I. New York: Springer-Verlag. (2004). doi: 10.1007/978-1-4757-4296-1_1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

3. Fischer B, Derman E, Toy W. A one-factor model of interest rates and its application to treasury bond options. Financ Analy J. (1990) 46:33–9. doi: 10.2469/faj.v46.n1.33

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

4. Derman E. My Life as a Quant. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (2004).

Google Scholar

5. Buetow GW, Hanke B, Fobozzi FJ. Impact of different interest rate models on bond value measures. J Fixed Income. (2001) 11:41–53. doi: 10.3905/jfi.2001.319304

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

6. Fabozzi FJ. Fixed Income Analysis, 2nd edition. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (2007).

Google Scholar

7. Hull JC. Options, Futures and Other Derivatives, 11th edition. New York: Pearson. (2022).

Google Scholar

Keywords: Black-Derman-Toy model, zero-coupon bond, instantaneous mean return, instantaneous volatility, inherent upturn probability, empirical research

Citation: He Y, Hu Y and Rachev S (2023) The implied views of bond traders on the spot equity market. Front. Appl. Math. Stat. 9:1324079. doi: 10.3389/fams.2023.1324079

Received: 18 October 2023; Accepted: 16 November 2023;
Published: 01 December 2023.

Edited by:

Young Shin Aaron Kim, Stony Brook University, United States

Reviewed by:

Claire Y. T. Chen, Montpellier Business School, France
Sergio Ortobelli Lozza, University of Bergamo, Italy

Copyright © 2023 He, Hu and Rachev. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Yifan He, Yifan.He@ttu.edu

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.