Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Phys., 17 July 2024
Sec. Social Physics
This article is part of the Research Topic Real-World Applications of Game Theory and Optimization, Volume II View all 7 articles

“Zero-sum game” or “win-win cooperation”: an analysis of the evolution effect of competition neutrality based on the participation of four parties

  • 1School of Finance and Economics, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang, China
  • 2School of Accounting, Shanghai Lixin University of Accounting and Finance, Shanghai, China
  • 3School of Business Administration, Shanghai Lixin University of Accounting and Finance, Shanghai, China

To effectively grasp the interactive evolution mechanism of relevant entities in the process of competitive neutrality and reveal the impact of the implementation effect of the principle of competitive neutrality on the evolution path of the game system is the key to guiding the development of the government, industry associations and enterprises with reasonable policies. The equilibrium point of the game is analyzed by the four-party evolutionary game model, and the influence of the change of relevant parameters on the evolution result of the game system is further simulated by numerical simulation. The results show that the central government supervision plays an important role in guiding the strategy selection of different game players. By raising the penalty standards for non-neutral competitive behavior of market players and increasing the non-neutral penalty for local governments, the system can evolve faster to the ideal state of “loose supervision by the central government, neutral implementation by local governments, strong supervision by industry associations, and active cooperation by enterprises.” Therefore, to improve the execution effect of competitive neutrality, the central government shall formulate a reasonable regulatory system, and to maximize inspire the enthusiasm of local government, industry associations and enterprises, to promote stability in the sustainable development of the market.

1 Introduction

The Report of the 20th National Congress of the Communist Party of China stressed that China should promote high-level opening-up and steadily expand the opening-up of rules, regulations, management and standards. Competitive neutrality as a regulation principle, policy orientation, order state or related institutional arrangement. Adhering to the principle of competitive neutrality is an important way to protect the equality of property rights and legitimate interests of various forms of ownership. However, in recent years, the participation of industry associations has gradually increased. For example: In 2021, the Health Bureau of a certain county in Hunan reached an agreement with Sinopharm Holding Company to issue mandatory targets for drug procurement by county public medical institutions, severely restricting fair competition in the drug market. Afterwards, the Medical Association specially organized personnel to actively publicize the Anti-Monopoly Law, the Implementation Rules of the Fair Competition Review System and other legal and policy provisions to the public to maintain a fair market environment. The relevant subjects of my country’s competitive neutrality principle are expanding from the traditional three parties to four parties. This article establishes a four-party competitive neutral dynamic game model of the central government-local government-industry associations-enterprises to explore the interactive relationship between the various subjects in the system, which is of great significance for promoting the coordination of the interests of all parties and improving the implementation effect of the principle of competitive neutrality.

In recent years, domestic and foreign scholars have conducted a large number of in-depth studies on the connotation and logical construction of competitive neutrality, which mainly involve four aspects: First, the universal practical research on competitive neutrality, which mainly explores the general rules of a country’s practice of competitive neutrality [14]. and practices [57]. The second is research on the application of competitive neutrality in specific countries, such as developing countries [8], Australia [9], India [10], China [1, 7, 11], etc. The third is research on the application of competitive neutrality in specific industries and fields, such as banking and securities industries [12], telecommunications networks [1315], and public-private cooperation fields [1618], domestic scholars have paid a lot of attention to the application of competitive neutrality in the reform of state-owned enterprises ([19]; Smith et.al., 2023). The fourth is the research on the application of competitive neutrality in international economic and trade rules, which mainly introduces the competitive neutrality rules in relevant economic and trade agreements and studies how China responds [2022]. In addition, domestic and foreign scholars have conducted a large number of in-depth studies on the implementation process of the principle of competitive neutrality based on game theory (Wang and Liu [2325]). First, regarding the game between the government and enterprises [26], established a complete information dynamic model of local governments and tobacco enterprises to study the impact on the development of the local tobacco industry under the conditions of local government’s protective taxation [27]. Constructed a “dual capability” game model of the competitiveness of large enterprises and found that government regulation and rent-seeking exist in society, and enterprises will allocate certain resources to obtain government support. Shi [28] constructed a two-level supply chain for game analysis and found that the government cannot effectively supervise the final product and downstream enterprises. The second is about the game between the central and local governments. Wang et al. [29] believe that the positive and negative external effects generated by competition between neighboring local governments are more sensitive, and both the central government and local governments are highly sensitive to the intensity of punishment. The third is about the game between local government, central government and enterprises [30]. found that by adjusting relevant parameters, enterprises can escape from a bad state and evolve into a good state. Wang and Liu [23] found that increasing the severity of penalties imposed by the central government on local governments can increase the enthusiasm of enterprises.

By reviewing previous research findings, it can be observed that many scholars have conducted in-depth studies on the interactive relationships among the participants involved in the implementation of the competition neutrality principle, as well as the influencing factors. The research focus has predominantly centered on the two-party or three-party game between the central and local governments, industry associations, and enterprises. However, the reality of competition neutrality involves a complex system of interactions among multiple entities. Solely investigating the two-party or three-party game relationships may lead to incomplete research results. In light of this, placing the central government, local government, industry associations, and enterprises simultaneously within a unified framework can compensate for the shortcomings of previous research and comprehensively analyze the dynamic evolution process of different participants’ strategic choices during the implementation of competition neutrality.

This paper constructs a four-party evolutionary game model of central government-local government-industry association and enterprise under the evolution effect of competitive neutrality, analyzes the evolutionary stable strategies under different circumstances, and uses numerical simulation to simulate the influence of the change of each parameter on the game system, so as to provide theoretical basis and policy reference for our country to improve the implementation effect of the competitive neutrality principle.

2 Construction of the four-party evolutionary game model: central government—local government—industry association—enterprise

2.1 Problem description and basic model assumptions

Under the background of China’s high-level opening up, the introduction of the competition neutrality principle by the government will exert a positive coercive effect, facilitating the better achievement of economic development goals. The central government, by formulating competition neutrality policies, mandates subordinate governments to implement measures to improve the local business environment. Due to the limited regulatory capacity of the central government, it is possible for local governments to vigorously support state-owned enterprises and restrain other ownership enterprises to seek private interests, leading to the potential loss of a fair competitive market environment.

Driven by the goal of maximizing profits, enterprises may choose to passively cooperate with the implementation of policies. Simultaneously, industry associations, as a service platform to communicate the relationship between government and enterprises, will spontaneously supervise local governments’ non-neutral treatment of all enterprises, thus influencing the utility levels of both central and local governments and the profits of all enterprises. To address this issue, this study constructs a four-party game model of competition neutrality effects with government participation, and the logical relationship among the game participations is depicted in Figure 1.

Figure 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1. Logic relationships of multi-participant competition neutrality effect game model.

To construct a game model to build a game model among stakeholders based on the principle of competition neutrality, the central government, local governments, industry associations and enterprises interact and influence each other, the following basic assumptions are proposed following the aforementioned context.

Assumption 1:. Selecting the central government, local government, industry associations, and enterprises as the game players. The probability of strong supervision by the central government is x, and the probability of weak supervision is 1-x; The probability of local government treating enterprises neutrally is y, and the probability of non-neutral treatment is 1-y; The probability of industry association actively supervising the behavior of government and enterprises is z, and the probability of passively supervising the behavior of government and enterprises is 1-z; The probability of enterprises actively cooperating with the government is m, and the probability of passively cooperating with the government is 1-m; x, y, z, m∈[0,1]. Expanding to the entire societal group, each probability can be interpreted as the proportion of the entire group of game participants selecting a certain strategy. All four entities are risk-neutral, to maximize their interests.

Assumption 2:. Local governments choose to adopt the principle of competition neutrality, and fair treatment of all enterprises will bring them benefits Q. Adopting neutrality towards all enterprises requires more personnel and time, resulting in execution costs of C1, while adopting non-neutrality towards all enterprises results in execution costs of C2; Since the supervision of industry associations is closely related to government-enterprise relations when local governments issue relevant policy documents, the industry associations actively communicate to bring benefits, which are denoted as T. The cost of active supervision is C3, and the cost of passive supervision is C4. The supervisory effectiveness of industry associations indirectly affects the decision-making behavior of enterprises. Some enterprises, upon seeing industry association supervision, are willing to spend more effort to actively cooperate, incurring additional costs of C5; After the central government issues policy guidance documents, the cost of strict supervision is C6, while the cost of lenient supervision is C7.

Assumption 3:. The local government actively adhering to the competition neutrality principle convey a signal of fair treatment to all enterprises, making enterprises willing to cooperate and winning the trust for the central government. The positive effects brought to enterprises and the central government are B1 and B2 respectively. The local government treat all enterprises in a non-neutral way and falsely cooperate with the policies of the central government, which brings negative effects to enterprises and the central government, denoted as N1 and N2 respectively.

Assumption 4:. If the central government supervises local governments before they treat all enterprises in a non-neutral way, stops all unfair behaviors in time, and punishes local governments and relevant trade associations, assuming that the penalties imposed by the central government on local governments and trade associations are F1 and F2 respectively, it can effectively avoid the non-neutral treatment of local governments and reduce social losses.

Assumption 5:. When the non-neutral treatment behavior of local governments is publicly exposed throughout society if all enterprises continue to actively cooperate with the implementation of higher-level requirements, then the reputational loss incurred by the local governments due to questioning is denoted as R1, and the reputational loss incurred by industry associations due to the inability to communicate and provide services promptly is denoted as R2. If all enterprises choose to passively cooperate, resisting non-neutral behavior through means such as strikes, the reputational loss incurred by the local governments is denoted as R3, and the reputational loss incurred by industry associations is denoted as R4.

According to the above assumptions, the payoff matrix for the four-game players can be obtained as shown in Table 1.

Table 1
www.frontiersin.org

Table 1. Payoff matrix of four-party game stages between central government, local government, industry association, and enterprises.

2.2 Replication dynamic equation construction

2.2.1 Replication of dynamic equations for the central government

The expected payoff of the central government is denoted as EX, where EX1 represents the expected payoffs when the central government enforces strict supervision, and EX2 represents the expected payoffs when the central government adopts lenient supervision.

EX1=yzmB2 C6+yz1mB2 C6+y1zmB2 C6+y1z1mB2 C6+1yzmN2C7+1yz1mN2C7+1y1zmN2+F1+F2C6+1y1z1mN2+F1+F2C6=C7C6+F1+F2yz+B2F1F2+N2y+C6C7F1F2z
EX2=yzmB2 C7+yz1mB2 C7+y1zmB2 C7+y1z1mB2 C7+1yzmN2C7+1yz1mN2C7+1y1zmN2C7+1y1z1mN2C7=B2+N2yC7N2

According to the above equations, the replication dynamic equation Fx of the central government is as follows:

Fx=dxdt=xEX1EX=x1xEX1EX2=xx1C7C6+F1+F2yz+F1+F2y+C7C6+F1+F2zC7C6+F1+F2Fx=2x1C7C6+F1+F2yz+F1+F2y+C7C6+F1+F2zC7C6+F1+F2

According to the stability theorem of differential equations, the conditions that the central government must satisfy to choose strict regulation to achieve stability is:

Fx=0 and Fx<0

When y=y0=C7C6+F1+F21zC7C6+F1+F2z+F1+F2, Fx=0, the stability strategy cannot be determined; When 0<y<y0=C7C6+F1+F21zC7C6+F1+F2z+F1+F2, to ensure Fx<0, we should choose strict supervision strategy, otherwise we should choose loose supervision strategy.

2.2.2 Replication of dynamic equations for the local government

The expected payoff of the local government is denoted as EY, where EY1 represents the expected payoffs when the local government adopts competition neutrality, and EY2 represents the expected payoffs when the local government passively adopts non-competition neutrality.

EY1=xzmQC1+xz1mQC1+x1zmQC1+x1z1mQC1+1xzmQC1+1xz1mQC1+1x1zmQC1+1x1z1mQC1
EY2=xzmC2+xz1mC2+x1zmC2F1+x1z1mC2F1+1xzmC2+1xz1mC2+1x1zmC2R1+1x1z1mC2R3
EY=yEY1+1yEY2=R1R3xyzmF1R3xyzR1R3xymR1R3xzmR1R3yzm+F1R3xy+F1R3xz+R1R3xmR3yz+R1R3ym+R1R3zmF1R3x+C2C1+R3+Uy+R3zR1R3mC2R3

According to the above equations, the replication dynamic equation Fy of the local government is as follows:

Fy=dydt=yEY1EY=y1yEY1EY2=yy1R1R3xzmF1R3xzR1R3xmR1R3zm+F1R3xR3z+R1R3m+C2C1+R3+QFy=12yR1R3xzmF1R3xzR1R3xmR1R3zm+F1R3xR3z+R1R3m+C2C1+R3+Q

According to the stability theorem of differential equations, the conditions that the local government must satisfy to choose strict regulation to achieve stability is:

Fy=0 and Fy<0

When m=m0=F1R3xz1+R3z1+C1C2QR1R31x1z, Fy=0, the stability strategy cannot be determined; When 0<m<m0=R21y+C4C3F2R2y1, to ensure Fy<0, we should choose competitive neutral strategy, otherwise we should choose non-competitive neutral strategy.

2.2.3 Replication of dynamic equations for the industry association

The expected payoff of the industry association is denoted as EZ, where EZ1 represents the expected payoffs when the industry association actively supervises, and EZ2 represents the expected payoffs when the industry association passively supervises.

EZ1=xymTC3+xy1mTC3+x1ymC3+x1y1mC3+1xymTC3+1xy1mTC3+1x1ymC3+1x1y1mC3
EZ2=xymTC4+xy1mTC4+x1ymC4F2+x1y1mC4F2+1xymTC4+1xy1mTC4+1x1ymC4R2+1x1y1mC4R4
EZ=zEZ1+1zEZ2=F2R2xyz+F2R2xy+F2R2xzR2yzF2R2x+R2+Ty+C4+R2C3zC4R2

According to the above equations, the replication dynamic equation Fz of the industry associations is as follows:

Fz=dzdt=zEZ1EZ=z1zEZ1EZ2=zz1F2R2xyF2R2x+R2y+C3C4R2Fz=2z1F2R2xyF2R2x+R2y+C3C4R2

According to the stability theorem of differential equations, the conditions that the industry associations must satisfy to choose strict regulation to achieve stability is:

Fz=0 and Fz<0

When x=x0=R21y+C4C3F2R2y1, Fz=0, the stability strategy cannot be determined; When 0<x<x0=R21y+C4C3F2R2y1, to ensure Fz<0, we should choose active supervision strategy, otherwise we should choose the negative supervision strategy.

2.2.4 Replication of dynamic equations for the enterprises

The expected payoff of the enterprise is denoted as EM, where EM1 represents the expected payoffs when the enterprises cooperate actively, and EM2 represents the expected payoffs when the enterprises cooperate passively.

EM1=xyzB1 C5+xy1zB1 C5+x1yzN1C5+x1y1zN1C5+1xyzB1 C5+1xy1zB1 C5+1x1yzN1 C5+1x1y1zN1 C5
EM2=xyzB1+xy1zB1+x1yzN1+x1y1zN1+1xyzB1+1xy1zB1+1x1yzN1+1x1y1zN1
EM=mEM1+1mEM2=B1+N1yC5mN1
Fm=dmdt=mEM1EM=m1mEM1EM2=mm1C5Fm=2m1C5

When 0<m<12, Fm<0, then choose the active cooperation strategy.

3 Analysis of the stable strategy of the four-party evolutionary game

3.1 Analysis of the equilibrium points

Let Fx=dxdt=0Fy=dydt0Fz=dzdt=0Fm=dmdt0 We can get that the equation has 24 or 16 equilibrium solutions of pure strategies, which are (0, 0, 0, 0)(0, 0, 0, 1)(0, 0, 1, 0)(0, 0, 1, 1)(0, 1, 0, 0)(0, 1, 0, 1)(0, 1, 1, 0)(0, 1, 1, 1)(1, 0, 0, 0)(1, 0, 0, 1)(1, 0, 1, 0)(1, 0, 1, 1)(1, 1, 0, 0)(1, 1, 0, 1)(1, 1, 1, 0)and (1, 1, 1, 1), along with one mixed strategy point (x*, y*, z*, m*). Pointed out that the stable solutions in multi-population evolutionary games are strict Nash equilibria, and strict Nash equilibria must be pure strategies. Therefore, this study will analyze the stability of the pure strategy equilibrium points.

Based on the replicator dynamic equations of each game player, the Jacobian matrix J of the replicator dynamic system is obtained.

J=FxxFxyFxzFxmFyxFyyFyzFymFzxFzyFzzFzmFmxFmyFmzFmm

3.2 Stability analysis of strategy combinations under strict regulation by the central government

When the central government adopts strict regulation, it satisfies the condition: C7C6+F1+F2yz+F1+F2y+C7C6+F1+F2zC7C6+F1+F2<0.The asymptotic analysis of the equilibrium points for the replicator dynamic system is presented in Table 2.

Table 2
www.frontiersin.org

Table 2. Asymptotic stability analysis of equilibrium points in the replicator dynamic system under strict regulation by the central government.

As can be seen from the above table, there is a (1,0,0,0) pure strategic stability point, which means that the central government has strong supervision, local governments implement the principle of non-neutral competition, industry associations adopt loose supervision and enterprises maintain a negative cooperative attitude.

From the equilibrium point (1,1,0,0), it can be seen that when the central government chooses strict regulation as the stability strategy, the local government’s stability strategy is to adopt the principle of competitive neutrality to treat all enterprises, the industry association adopts the strategy of passive supervision, and the enterprises adopt a negative attitude to cooperate with the implementation of the policy. However, the choice of local governments is unstable. At this point, the central government can carry out appropriate loose regulation, give local governments and industry associations appropriate flexibility, encourage enterprises to actively participate, create a good atmosphere of competition and cooperation, and promote local governments to actively implement the principle of competition neutrality positively.

3.3 Stability analysis of strategy combinations under lenient regulation by the central government

When the central government adopts lenient regulation, it satisfies the condition: C7C6+F1+F2yz+F1+F2y+C7C6+F1+F2zC7C6+F1+F2<0 The asymptotic analysis of the equilibrium points for the replicator dynamic system is presented in Table 3.

Table 3
www.frontiersin.org

Table 3. Asymptotic stability analysis of equilibrium points in the replicator dynamic system under lenient regulation by the central government.

There exist two pure strategy stable points: (0,0,0,0) and (0,1,0,0). Among them, (0,1,0,0) indicates that the local government actively responds to the call of the central government and encourage equal competition among all enterprises in its jurisdiction. Industry associations and enterprises lag behind government departments in their understanding of policies, so they adopt a cautious and conservative attitude to cooperation. According to the stability theorem of differential equations, if the local government adopts the principle of competitive neutrality as a stable state, the conditions must be satisfied: Fy=0 and Fy<0, in other words, fulfilling m<R21y+C4C3F2R2y1.

(0,0,0,0) indicates that in the context of loose regulation by the central government, local governments, industry associations, and enterprises maintain a reserved attitude towards neutral competitive principles and are unwilling to actively cooperate in implementation. To avoid such situations, we should give full play to the communication and cooperation functions of government personnel and industry associations, along with effective publicity efforts, to build a positive image for the government and relevant parties, thereby avoiding the situation where (0,0,0,0) becomes a stable equilibrium point.

In the new era of the simultaneous development of diverse economic systems, overly lenient supervision by the central government is not conducive to the formation of an orderly and fair economic environment. To prevent local governments from adopting non-neutral competitive principles, which means unfair treatment of all enterprises, the central government departments can take measures of both rewards and penalties. This approach can encourage local government regulatory departments and relevant personnel from industry associations, who possess professional qualities and good integrity, to actively supervise and cooperate. It also assists various types of enterprises in understanding policies, thus making it a stable strategy.

4 Simulation analysis of the evolutionary game

Based on the above analysis, to more visually observe the evolutionary paths of multi-party game players under different constraints and regulatory strategies and the impact on the evolution results, this paper uses MATLAB2018 to simulate the evolution trajectory of each game player and uses ode instruction to solve the replication dynamic equation.

4.1 Initial system simulation settings

Initially, it is assumed that the probabilities of the central government, local government, industry association, and enterprises choosing the strategies of strict regulation, neutral treatment, active supervision, and active cooperation are [0.5, 0.5, 0.5, 0.5] respectively. The horizontal axis represents time (t), and the vertical axis represents the probabilities (p) of the central government (x), local government (y), industry association (z), and enterprises (m) choosing their respective strategies. The initial parameter settings are shown in Table 4.

Table 4
www.frontiersin.org

Table 4. Parameter setting.

4.2 Impact of parameter changes on the system

4.2.1 Impact of central government regulatory costs

Setting C6 = {2, 6, 12}, the evolutionary process and outcomes of the four-party game players are illustrated in Figure 2.

Figure 2
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 2. The impact of central government regulatory costs on the evolutionary strategies of each party.

As shown in Figure 2, the level of central government regulatory costs not only affects the evolutionary trend of the central government’s strategies but also influences the evolutionary trends of the other three parties. When the regulatory costs of the central government increase, the probability of proactive supervision by industry associations gradually rises and tends to stabilize. Therefore, by raising the regulatory costs of the central government, it can not only stimulate the supervision efficiency of industry associations but also provide service communication to local governments and all enterprises.

4.2.2 Impact of local Government’s neutral competition policy

Setting R1 = {12, 25, 50}, R2 = {6, 15, 35}, the evolutionary process and outcomes of the four-party game players are illustrated in Figure 3.

Figure 3
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 3. The impact of local government's non-neutral competition policy on the evolutionary strategies of each party.

From Figure 3, it is evident that when non-neutral competitive behavior by local governments becomes public and results in a gradual increase in reputational losses for the central government and industry associations, the probability of active cooperation by enterprises will continuously decrease to zero, ultimately transitioning to passive cooperation and stabilizing. This indicates that enterprises can adjust their response to non-neutral treatment of various businesses by local governments based on the influence of the central government and industry associations in society. It is essential to maintain rationality, actively address various unfair situations, and create maximum social value.

4.2.3 Impact of industry association regulatory costs

Setting C3 = {2, 10, 25}, the evolutionary process and outcomes of the four-party game players are illustrated in Figure 4.

Figure 4
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 4. The impact of industry association supervision costs on the evolutionary strategies of each party.

From Figure 4, it can be observed that the level of supervision costs for industry associations has an impact on the intensity of central government regulation, the implementation of neutral policies by local governments, and the degree of cooperation by enterprises. When the supervision cost C3 = 2, the probabilities of the central government, local government, and enterprises gradually decrease to zero, with local governments and enterprises exhibiting a faster-declining trend. However, when the supervision costs C3 = 10 or C3 = 25, the probability of local governments adopting a neutral competition principle is significantly increased, benefiting both the central government and enterprises.

4.2.4 The impact of enterprises cooperating with neutral competition principles

Setting C5 = {2, 10, 25}, the evolutionary process and outcomes of the four-party game players are illustrated in Figure 5.

Figure 5
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 5. The impact of enterprise cooperation costs on the evolutionary strategies of each party.

From Figure 5, it is evident that after observing industry association supervision, enterprises are willing to devote more effort to active cooperation. The level of additional cost C5 will affect the evolutionary trends of the central government, local government, and industry association. When the additional cost C5 = 1, the probabilities of the other three parties are all decreasing and finally approaching 0. When the additional cost C5 = 10, the probability of active supervision by industry associations gradually decreases to 0.2 and then remains stable. However, when the additional cost C5 = 25, the probability of the central government increases and eventually stabilizes at 1.

4.2.5 Impact of central government regulatory probability

Setting x = {0,0.8}, the evolutionary process and outcomes of the four-party game players are illustrated in Figure 6.

Figure 6
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 6. The impact of central government regulatory probability on the evolutionary strategies of each party.

Setting the probability of the central government’s participation in regulation x as x = 0 and x = 0.8 respectively, we explore the evolutionary paths of different strategies of local government, industry associations, and enterprises in three-dimensional space under the states of regulation and non-regulation by the central government, and conduct simulation analysis. The simulation results are shown in Figure 6.

From Figure 6, when x = 0, indicating that the central government does not regulate whether the local government effectively implements neutral competitive principles, various situations exist regarding the stable strategies of the local government under the influence of factors such as reputation loss. The industry associations are more inclined to maintain the existing government-enterprise relationship through passive supervision. When x = 0.8, indicating that the central government implements strict supervision and inspection mechanisms on the local government, although there is no stable strategy in the replicating dynamic equation system, if the central government regulatory department maintains a certain degree of regulatory probability, the probability of active supervision by the industry association will significantly increase and stabilize at active supervision. In this case, enterprises can maintain trust in both the local and central governments.

5 Conclusion and recommendations

5.1 Main conclusions

By establishing a four-way evolutionary game model of central government, local government, industry association, and enterprise, this paper analyzes the analyze the stable strategies under different situations and uses simulation analysis to examine the evolutionary paths of the impact of parameter changes on the system. The following conclusions can be drawn from the analysis:

(1) Among the 16 pure strategy equilibrium points in the four-party evolutionary game system, there are a total of 4 conditionally stable points, while the remaining 12 equilibrium points are unstable under any conditions. These four conditionally stable points represent the possible strategic equilibrium of various stakeholders under the principle of competition neutrality. When the relative net income of a certain strategy in the strategy set is positive, related participants will be more inclined to choose this strategy.

(2) Through numerical simulation analysis, it is found that increasing the punishment intensity of the central government towards the local government’s passive implementation of competition-neutral principles and enhancing the supervision of industry associations can not only boost the local government’s enthusiasm for implementing competition neutral principles but also increase the probability of industry associations actively supervising non-neutral competition behaviors of local governments and enterprises. Raising the punishment standards for non-neutral competition behaviors of market entities and increasing the penalties for non-neutral actions by local governments will have an impact on the strategic choices of local governments, industry associations, and enterprises, which would make the system evolve more rapidly toward the ideal state of “loose supervision by the central government, the neutral implementation by local governments, strong supervision by industry associations and active cooperation by enterprises.” However, excessively lenient central government regulation will hinder the game system from reaching a stable state, making it an ineffective governance model in the long run. Finally, recommendations for constructing the principle of competitive neutrality are proposed from the perspectives of central government, local government, industry associations, and enterprises.

5.2 Policy recommendations

Based on the research conclusions above, the following policy recommendations can be proposed:

For the central government, establishing a unified legal system and policies, strengthening supervision and law enforcement, and ensuring information transparency and openness are effective ways to punish unfair monopolies and unfair competition. By establishing a competition-neutral supervision mechanism, the central government can effectively reduce the inaction of local governments and the speculative behavior of industry associations. While implementing the relevant legal responsibilities of local governments, it actively promotes the combination of cloud computing, big data and artificial intelligence, reduces regulatory costs, and takes appropriate measures to solve social problems in a timely manner.

For local governments, they must actively implement central policies and create a level playing field. We will strictly implement the central government’s policies and regulations on competitive neutrality and avoid local protectionism and policy bias. We will treat all enterprises the same in terms of attracting investment and government procurement, and avoid favoring local enterprises or state-owned enterprises in support policies. At the same time, the approval process is simplified, business costs are reduced, and the overall level of the local business environment is improved.

For industry associations, it is necessary to maintain a neutral attitude, rationally view the commitments of local governments and enterprises, and play the role of middlemen. Encourage industry associations to actively learn the essentials of the principle of competitive neutrality and publicize popular science to enterprises and the public, formulate and promote industry self-discipline norms, and ensure that member enterprises comply with the principle of competitive neutrality. By coordinating the cooperation among members to jointly deal with the challenges of the industry, advocate fair competition, prevent monopoly and unfair competition in the industry, and ensure the sustainable and healthy development of the entire industry.

For enterprises, they need to abide by the law, abide by the national anti-monopoly law, anti-unfair competition law and other laws and regulations, establish and improve internal compliance mechanisms to ensure that they follow the principle of competitive neutrality in their daily operations. Actively feedback the problems encountered in competitive neutrality to the government and industry associations, undertake corporate social responsibility, actively participate in public welfare and social services, and establish a good corporate image.

In summary, by promoting fair competition among enterprises, the central government aims to improve the economic environment of the entire country to support sustainable development; by decentralizing power to local governments, improving the reward and punishment mechanism, and rewarding entities that actively create a fair competitive environment, Increase punishment for entities whose powers and responsibilities are not clear and allow unfair monopoly and unfair competition to occur, strictly examine the relationship between government and business, and urge local government departments to actively rectify; severely punish industry associations that passively supervise for the sake of profit, and punish speculative industry associations Supervise through fines, notifications and criticisms, severely crack down on non-neutral competition, and be responsible to society.

Data availability statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary Material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author contributions

YZ: Conceptualization, Writing–original draft, Writing–review and editing, Data curation, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Supervision. MW: Conceptualization, Formal Analysis, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Project administration, Supervision, Validation, Writing–review and editing. JL: Data curation, Formal Analysis, Methodology, Project administration, Software, Validation, Writing–review and editing.

Funding

The author(s) declare that financial support was received for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. This research was funded by The National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant numbers 72072076 and 72372106, Postgraduate Research & Practice Innovation Program of Jiangsu Province, grant numbers KYCX24 3906, Shanghai Lixin University of Accounting and Finance (JXYJ2023001).

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

The handling editor DH declared a shared affiliation with the author YZ at the time of review.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

1. Xu SY A new approach to the regulation of administrative monopoly behavior from the perspective of competition policy. ECUPL J (2015) 18(04):27–39. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1008-4622.2015.04.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

2. Shi JZ Several issues in strengthening the fair competition review system. Adm Reform (2017)(01) 43–6. doi:10.14150/j.cnki.1674-7453.2017.01.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

3. Chang YL Tong-Shui X, Tao Y U, et al. Research on Evolutionary Game of Government Regulation and Production of Manufacturers in the Angle of Low Carbon. Chin J Manag Sci (2019). doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2019.11.010

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

4. Ying PG From trade policy to competition policy: the path choice of establishing international state-owned enterprises rules. World Economy Stud (2022)(03) 123–33+136. doi:10.13516/j.cnki.wes.2022.03.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

5. Capobianco A, Christiansen H. Competitive neutrality and state-owned enterprises: challenges and policy options. Oecd Corporate Governance Working Pap (2011). doi:10.1787/5kg54cwps0s3-en

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

6. Muggy L, Stamm JLH. Game theory applications in humanitarian operations: a review. J Humanitarian Logistics Supply Chain Manag (2011). doi:10.1108/JHLSCM-07-2013-0026

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

7. Liu CY, Xia TS, Yu T. Research on evolutionary game of government regulation and production of manufacturer in the angle of low carbon. Chin J Manag Sci (2019) 27(11):96–106. doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2019.11.010

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

8. Healey D, Smith RL, Bai X. Competitive neutrality: OECD recommendations and the Australian experience. J competition L Econ (2023) 19:250–76. doi:10.1093/joclec/nhad003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

9. Rennie M, Lindsay F. Competitive neutrality and state-owned enterprises in Australia: review of practices and their relevance for other countries. In: OECD corporate governance working papers. OECD (2011).

Google Scholar

10. Bhattacharjea A (2015). The Competition Commission of India imposes a structural remedy while approving an acquisition agreement between two multinational cement firms (Holcim/Lafarge)

Google Scholar

11. Yan ZQ, Li WL. Fair Competition Review and Competitive Neutrality of Government Subsidies [J]. J financ econ. (2023) 49(10):124–138. doi:10.1016/j.intfin.2022.101625

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

12. Benink HA, Llewellyn DT. Fragile banking in Norway, Sweden and Finland: an empirical analysis. J Int Financial Markets Institutions Money (1994) 4(3):5–19. doi:10.1007/BF01051758

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

13. Gans JS, King SP. Competitive neutrality in access pricing. Aust Econ Rev (2005) 38(2):128–36. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8462.2005.00361.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

14. Bourreau M, Cambini C, Hoernig S. Geographic access markets and investments. Inf Econ Pol (2015) 31:13–21. doi:10.1016/j.infoecopol.2015.04.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

15. Hashim Z, Wang Y, Dinara GV, Abbas Q. Exploring a pathway to carbon neutrality via reinforcing environmental performance through green process innovation, environmental orientation and green competitive advantage. J Environ Manag (2021) 296:113383. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.113383

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

16. Zwalf S, Hodge G, Alam Q. Choose your own adventure: finding a suitable discount rate for evaluating value for money in public–private partnership proposals. Aust J Public Adm (2017) 76(3):301–15. doi:10.1111/1467-8500.12242

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

17. Wang C China's opening-up and the SOEs’ competitive neutrality principle. Int Econ Trade Res (2023) 39(02):88–105. doi:10.13687/j.cnki.gjjmts.20230217.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

18. Tang Q, Deng WQ. Financial policy competition neutrality and the efficiency of outward foreign direct investment. Int Rev Financial Anal (2024) 92:103076. doi:10.1016/j.irfa.2024.103076

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

19. Ping C, Junmin W, Hong W. Evolutionary game analysis on rent-seeking regulation of government procurement in the tripartite model. J Nanjing Univ Finance Econ (2010).

Google Scholar

20. Wei YF, Huang JW, Song M, Zhan XS (2007). A cross-layer adaptive approach for cooperative radio resource management in multi-radio access environment. In: ICPCA 2007. 2nd International Conference on IEEE. Birmingham, UK: IEEE.

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

21. Virtanen M, Valkama P. Competitive neutrality and distortion of competition: a conceptual view. World Competition (2009) 32:393–407. doi:10.54648/woco2009037

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

22. Zhang CY Review of the dual approach to monopoly agreements and the reconstruction of prohibition rules: starting from the hub-and-spoke agreement. Stud L Business (2018) 35(02):102–13. doi:10.16390/j.cnki.issn1672-0393.2018.02.027

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

23. Wang L, Liu XF. Research on regulation from the perspective of competition neutrality. Social Sci Guangdong (2020)(05) 41–7. doi:10.19581/j.cnki.ciejournal.2019.10.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

24. Chen J, Yang Z. Industrial technology policy under the new development pattern: theoretical logic, outstanding problems and optimization. Economist (2021)(02) 33–42. doi:10.16158/j.cnki.51-1312/f.2021.02.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

25. Jia KQ The dual characters of competitive neutrality. J Beijing Union Univ (Social Sciences) (2021) 9(04):56–63. doi:10.16255/j.cnki.11-5117c.2021.0052

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

26. Collins BC, Kumral M. Game theory for analyzing and improving environmental management in the mining industry. Resour Pol (2020) 2020:69. doi:10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101860

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

27. Maleki J, Masoumi Z, Hakimpour F, Coello Coello CA. A spatial land-use planning support system based on game theory. Land Use Policy (2020) 99:105013. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2020.105013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

28. Shi JZ The copyright internal interest balancing mechanism and intervention of anti-monopoly law: enlightenments from American digital performance rights in sound recordings mechanism. L Sci Mag (2018). doi:10.19851/j.cnki.cn11-1010/f.2018.08.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

29. Wang CHS, Leng M, Song J, Luo C, Hui S. Managing a supply chain under the impact of customer reviews: a two-period game analysis. Eur J Oper Res (2019) 277(2):454–68. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2019.02.033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

30. Lei X, Xiaohua T. Mechanism of interaction between Firm′s competitiveness and market scale from view of dual-competence technology economics (2012).

Google Scholar

Keywords: competitive neutrality, four-party game, numerical simulation, evolutionary game, simulation analysis

Citation: Zhu Y, Wu M and Lu J (2024) “Zero-sum game” or “win-win cooperation”: an analysis of the evolution effect of competition neutrality based on the participation of four parties. Front. Phys. 12:1429728. doi: 10.3389/fphy.2024.1429728

Received: 07 June 2024; Accepted: 17 June 2024;
Published: 17 July 2024.

Edited by:

Dun Han, Jiangsu University, China

Reviewed by:

Wentao Shan, Nanjing Audit University, China
Yan Tan, Yangzhou University, China

Copyright © 2024 Zhu, Wu and Lu. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Mengyun Wu, bWV3dUB1anMuZWR1LmNu

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.