Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Phys., 06 May 2024
Sec. Social Physics
This article is part of the Research Topic Real-World Applications of Game Theory and Optimization View all 17 articles

A game study on the impact of employees’ deviant innovation behaviors on firms’ organizational innovation performance

Han ZhengHan Zheng1Jie Lu
Jie Lu2*Yanxia ChenYanxia Chen3Yingying GuYingying Gu4Zixin ZhengZixin Zheng4
  • 1School of Finance and Economics, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang, Jiangsu, China
  • 2School of Business Administration, Shanghai Lixin School of Accounting and Finance, Shanghai, China
  • 3School of Management, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang, Jiangsu, China
  • 4School of Accounting, Shanghai Lixin School of Accounting and Finance, Shanghai, China

Organizational innovation performance is considered to be the key to maintaining competitiveness and achieving sustainable development in modern enterprises. Deviant innovation refers to that employees improve their working methods without the permission of the organization, break through the constraints of existing rules and achieve high performance. Additionally, Deviant innovation behavior can also stimulate the enthusiasm of other members of the organization. In order to study the evolutionary game rules of strategic interaction between enterprises and employees in the process of deviant innovation, this paper constructs a 2*2 asymmetric payoff matrix, and uses numerical simulation to show the influence of different values of decision parameters and changes of initial conditions on the evolutionary results. The research reveals that the interaction game between employees’ deviant innovation behavior and enterprise enhancement of organizational innovation performance is a complex and significant topic. It is found that when enterprises actively improve organizational innovation performance and employees implement deviant innovation behavior, both sides engage in positive game interactions, maximizing enterprise benefits. However, when enterprises passively enhance organizational innovation performance but employees engage in deviant innovation behavior, it may lead to conflicts between the two parties. The research findings provide relevant strategies for employees to correctly implement deviant innovation behavior and for enterprises to enhance organizational innovation performance.

1 Introduction

In modern enterprises, organizational innovation performance is considered to be the key to maintaining competitiveness and achieving sustainable development. However, innovation is no longer solely the responsibility of senior management but increasingly relies on employees at all levels within the organization. Deviant innovation refers to that employees improve their working methods without the permission of the organization, break through the constraints of existing rules and aim to improve the interests of the organization [1]. We find that employees’ positive deviant innovation behavior can prompt enterprises to better integrate and utilize internal and external resources, promote the landing of innovation culture, and accelerate the promotion of innovation projects, thus enhancing the innovation competitiveness of the enterprise and further optimizing the innovation performance of the organization [2].

Organizational innovation performance, as a comprehensive reflection of various innovation achievements of the enterprise, is expressed as the overall role and impact results brought to the enterprise from the generation of innovative ideas and the adoption of innovative measures to apply them to the actual production and operation activities, which itself is a multi-level concept [3]; [4]. This study believes that employees’ deviant innovation behaviors can motivate other members of the organization, trigger chain reactions internally, and promote broader innovation, thus greatly contributing to the improvement of organizational innovation performance. When enterprises actively enhance organizational innovation performance and provide sufficient resources and support, while employees also engage in deviant innovation behavior, an ideal state is achieved. At this point, employees and enterprises jointly achieve optimal interaction effects, creating a win-win situation [5].

Evolutionary game theory is an interdisciplinary fusion theory that combines evolutionary biology and classical game theory [6]. It views individual strategies and behaviors as continually evolving through the transmission of genetic information and random mutations. In evolutionary game theory, individual behaviors are strategies, and the evolutionary process is a dynamic game process. Individuals adapt and adjust their strategies by considering the pros and cons of different strategies [7].

Currently, evolutionary game theory has become one of the primary mathematical tools for research in economics and finance [8]. In recent years, numerous scholars both domestically and internationally have conducted research in this field. Eid et al. [9] finds out the balanced distribution of post-disaster insurance plans purchased by households and sold by insurance companies and post-disaster relief implemented by government agencies. Feng and Hu [10] investigated the evolutionary game of financing empowerment mechanisms for the digital transformation of small and medium-sized enterprises, exploring the impacts of core enterprise support and government subsidies on the digital transformation financing of small and medium-sized enterprises.

In the practice of enterprises enhancing innovation performance and employees engaging in deviant innovative behavior, evolutionary game theory also provides a practical analytical framework. When employees are faced with different company innovation atmospheres and leadership decisions, their choices regarding deviant innovation exhibit characteristics of evolutionary game theory. Similarly, when enterprises decide on the level of investment in innovation, they consider various factors such as employee capabilities, operational objectives, and return on investment [11]. However, in situations of incomplete information, they often make decisions based on personal experience and habits, leading to interactive games between both parties. Therefore, to study the interaction between enterprises and employees, this paper constructs a dynamic game model composed of enterprises and employees.

2 Model description

Due to the short-sighted behavior under the condition of limited rationality, in the process of innovation, whether the enterprise actively improves the organizational innovation performance and the employee’s deviant innovation behavior is a dynamic process of continuous adjustment, similar to the characteristics in ecology. Enterprises, considering long-term benefits, may to some extent enhance organizational innovation performance [12]. However, their performance may be influenced by employees’ deviant innovation behavior, which can manifest in two ways: 1) positively enhancing organizational innovation performance (A1) with a probability of p; 2) negatively enhancing organizational innovation performance (A2) with a probability of 1-p.

Similarly, assuming that the employees will initially engage in deviant innovation behaviors, and during the process from initiating deviant innovation to executing it, they will continuously adjust their behavior patterns. Therefore, the employees will also have two choices: 1) to carry out the deviant innovation behavior (B1), with the probability of q; 2) not to carry out the deviant innovation behavior (B2), with the probability of 1-q, the payoff matrix for the two sides of the game as shown in Table 1.

Table 1
www.frontiersin.org

Table 1. Game Matrix of employee deviant innovation and organizational performance.

π1 and π2, respectively denote the basic profits of the company and employees themselves. K represents the investment made by the company to actively enhance organizational innovation performance, and X(K) represents the additional profit that can be gained due to the simultaneous enhancement of organizational innovation performance by the company and deviant innovative behavior by employees. 0 < X(K) < 1, that is, the more active the enterprise is in terms of organizational innovation performance, the greater the benefits of employees will be.

The interpretation of the matrix is as follows: 1) When the company actively improves its organizational innovation performance and the employees conduct deviant innovation behaviors, the company’s profit is represented as π1K+B, and the employees’ profit is represented as π2+XK+C. B is the revenue allocated from the “excess profit” gained by the employee from the deviant innovation, and C is the performance wage that the employee receives because he/she performs the innovative behavior and thus improves the organizational innovation performance of the firm. Where B > K, because in the long run, organizational innovation performance can improve the overall earnings of the enterprise, thus the profit obtained by the company through employees’ deviant innovative behaviors should be greater than the investment made in actively enhancing organizational innovation performance. 2) When the firm actively improves organizational innovation performance but the employees do not engage in deviant innovation behavior, the firm’s profit is π1K, and the employees’ profit is π2+XK. 3) When the firm negatively improves organizational innovation performance but employees engage in deviant innovation behavior, the firm’s profit is π1, and the employee’s profit is π2D. D denotes the loss incurred by employees when they persist in deviate innovation while the company negatively improves organizational innovation performance. In this case, team members may exhibit lower acceptance of conflict, lower identification with organizational goals, and less trust among members. (4) When the company passively enhances organizational innovation performance and employees do not engage in deviant innovation behaviors, the firm’s profit is π1, and the employees’ gain is π2. If the employees continue not to carry out the deviant innovation, the company will gradually lose its competitiveness, which will lead to the continuous attrition. Therefore, both parties in the game can only maintain the original profit within a certain period.

According to the Malthusian dynamic equation [13], which states that the growth rate of a strategy is equal to its relative fitness, specifically as long as the fitness of individuals adopting the strategy is higher than the average fitness of the group, the strategy will grow over time. Therefore, the dynamical equation for the strategic interaction between organizational innovation performance and employees’ deviant innovation over time is:

dpdt=p1pqBKdqdt=q1qC+DpD(1)

According to equation set (1), we can study the evolution of organizational innovation performance and employees’ strategic interaction behavior of deviant innovation. Let the Jacobian matrix of the system of equations (8.80) be J, then Eq. 2 can be derived.

J=12pqBKBp1pC+Dq1q12qC+DpD(2)

Denoting the determinant of J as Det(J), and then we can discuss the stability of the system of Eq. 1.

Let dpdt=0 and dpdt=0, 5 equilibria of the evolutionary game can be obtained on the plane M=p,q0p,q1: O (0,0), W (0,1), U (1,0), V (1,1), and E (DC+D,EB), and their stability is shown in Table 2.

Table 2
www.frontiersin.org

Table 2. Results of the analysis of the stability of the equilibrium point.

From Table 2, two of the five equilibrium points of the system are stable points, representing Evolutionarily Stable Strategies (ESS), corresponding to two game modes: 1) Mode (A1, B1) is that the employees engage in the deviant innovation behavior while the company positively enhances organizational innovation performance; 2) Mode (A2, B2) is that the employees do not engage in deviant innovation behavior while the enterprise passively enhances organizational innovation performance. Figure 1 illustrates the dynamic evolution process of organizational innovation performance and employees’ deviant innovation behavior.

Figure 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1. The dynamic process of business-employee engagement.

In Figure 1, the discount connected by two imbalance points (0,1), (1,0) and saddle point E (DC+D,KB) can be understood as the critical line where the system converges to different modes. If the initial position is located in the UEWO region, the system converges to the mode (A2, B2), which means the company negatively improves the organizational innovation performance, and the employees do not engage in deviant innovation behaviors. This is an undesirable locking state. Conversely, if the initial state is located in the UEWO region, the system converges to the mode (A1, B1), which means the company positively improves the organizational innovation performance, and the employees engage in deviant innovation behaviors. This is an ideal state. Both of these states are evolutionarily stable states, and participants adopting the alternative strategy will eventually vanish in evolution. Therefore, by adjusting parameters, the probability of the system reaching the ideal equilibrium state (A1, B1) can be increased.

When the parameters related to deviant innovation behavior and organizational innovation performance change, the speed of convergence of the model is also affected.

(1) The effect on the rate of convergence of the firm’s benefit B from the employee’s deviant innovation behavior and the employee’s deviant innovation and hence performance pay C. At the saddle point, δqδb<0, with other parameters unchanged, the saddle point E (DC+D,KB) translates downward, the probability of convergence to mode (A1,B1) increases, and the probability of convergence to mode (A2, B2) decreases; conversely, the probability of convergence to mode (A1, B1) decreases, and the probability of convergence to mode (A2, B2) increases, as shown in Figure 2. At the saddle point, δpδc<0, the saddle point E (DC+D,KB) is translated to the left. The probability of convergence to mode (A1, B1) increases and the probability of convergence to mode (A2, B2) decreases; conversely, the probability of convergence to mode (A1, B1) decreases and the probability of convergence to mode (A2, B2) increases as shown in Figure 3.

(2) Similarly, the impact of the company’s inputs K to improve the organizational innovation performance and the benefits X derived by the employees on the rate of convergence is shown in Figure 2. Because X′(K) > 0, indicating that within the domain of definition, a monotonic function possesses an inverse function, hence K′(X) > 0. This can be interpreted as follows: in an environment where employees actively strive to enhance organizational innovation performance, greater benefits can be obtained through the implementation of deviant innovation behaviors, thus promoting the survival and development of the enterprise. Consequently, the firm tends to invest more in this regard. X does not directly influence the convergence speed but affects it through the parameter K. In an environment where organizational innovation enhancement is lacking, the impact of loss D on the convergence speed when employees persist in implementing deviant innovation is depicted in Figure 3.

Figure 2
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 2. Effect of variation of parameters B, K on convergence rate. (A) When B increases and K decreases. (B) When B decreases and K increases.

Figure 3
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 3. Effect of variation of parameters C, D on convergence rate. (A) When C increases and D decreases. (B) When C decreases and D increases.

3 Simulation analysis

Next, by means of numerical experiments, we analyze the effects on the evolutionary results of the changes in parameters such as the proportion of the initial population choosing a certain strategy, the inputs carried out by enterprises to positively enhance the innovative performance of the organization, the additional benefits gained by the enterprises and the employees from the innovative behaviors, and the losses suffered by the employees who transgressed the innovation as a result of the negative enhancement of innovative performance of the organization.

(1) First of all, in this issue, we focus on the impact of the initial population proportion to choose the relevant strategy on the evolutionary outcome. The results of the numerical experiments are illustrated in Figure 4 below, where p and q respectively denote the initial proportions of firms choosing to actively enhance organizational innovation performance and the proportions of employees practicing deviant innovation behaviors. The horizontal axis represents time, and the vertical axis represents the proportion of employees who perform deviant innovative behaviors. The values of the parameters are K = 1, B = 2, C = 0.5, D = 1.

Figure 4
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 4. Effect of changes in the proportion of the initial population choosing a particular strategy on evolutionary outcomes. (A) p = 0.2. (B) p = 0.8.

From the figure, it can be observed that the evolutionary paths of employees’ deviant innovations and firms’ organizational innovation behaviors depend largely on the choice of initial probabilities. The four different trajectories start from different initial probabilities and do not intersect or overlap before converging to the equilibrium state. In addition, the time required to converge to the equilibrium state varies in relation to the initial proportion of the population whose employees perform the deviant innovation behavior. The closer the initial proportion is to the equilibrium state, the faster the convergence. Comparing the two sub-figures in Figure 2: we can see that the evolutionary outcome of employee behavior and the time of convergence are not only affected by the initial proportion of employees who choose deviant innovative behavior, but also by the initial proportion of the corporate population that actively improves the innovative performance of the organization. The closer the initial proportion is to the ideal state, the greater the possibility that the evolution of employee behavior will reach the ideal state.

(2) In order to understand the impact of firms’ inputs to enhance organizational innovation performance on evolutionary outcomes, we conducted numerical experiments, the results of which are shown in Figure 5 below. In the figure, the horizontal axis represents time and the vertical axis represents the proportion of firms that are actively engaged in strategies to enhance organizational innovation performance. The proportion of employees choosing to perform deviant innovative behaviors is 0.8 (q = 0.8), and the other parameters are B = 2, C = 0.5, and D = 1.

Figure 5
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 5. Impact of changes in firms’ inputs to actively improve organizational innovation performance on evolutionary outcomes. (A) k = 1. (B) k = 2.

Comparing the results in Figures 5A, B, we can observe that as the firm’s investment in enhancing organizational innovation performance increases, the interaction behavior between the firm and its employees evolves to a completely different state, namely, mode (A2, B2). In this pattern, firms adopt negative strategies to enhance organizational innovation performance, while employees no longer perform deviant innovation behaviors, which is an undesirable locking state. However, ideally firms should actively enhance organizational innovation performance, so it is important to note that more investment is not always better, because it may fall into an undesirable locking state after exceeding a certain limit.

(3) Changes in firms’ earnings have a significant impact on the evolutionary outcomes, and the results of the numerical experiments are shown in Figure 6. In the figure, the horizontal axis represents time, and the vertical axis represents the proportion of firms choosing to actively improve organizational innovation performance. The proportion of employees choosing to transgress innovation is 0.8, and the other parameters are K = 1, C = 0.5, and D = 1. By comparing the results in Figures 6A, B, it can be observed that the benefits that firms gain from the deviant innovation behaviors of their employees have a significant impact on the evolution of the interactive behaviors between firms and their employees to the desired state. When the proportion of employees engaging in deviant innovation is higher, the firm’s gain increases accordingly, which motivates the firm to be more active in improving organizational innovation performance, thus creating a win-win situation.

(4) The loss of deviant innovation behaviors suffered by employees has an impact on the evolutionary outcome in the case of firms taking negative measures to enhance organizational innovation performance, and the results of the numerical experiment are shown in Figure 7 below. In the figure, the horizontal axis represents time and the vertical axis represents the proportion of employees who choose deviant innovative behavior. The proportion of firms choosing to positively enhance organizational innovation performance is 0.8, and the other parameters are K = 1, B = 2, and C = 0.5. By comparing the results in Figures 7A, B, it can be observed that when the loss suffered by employees due to deviant innovation behaviors increases, it is more likely that the interaction behaviors between the firms and the employees will evolve into the (A2, B2) pattern. This is because if an employee’s deviant innovative behavior may lead to an increase in the likelihood or degree of task conflict escalating into emotional conflict, then the psychological loss suffered by the employee will increase accordingly, which may lead the employee to choose a more conservative strategy, i.e., not to engage in deviant innovative behavior.

Figure 6
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 6. Impact of changes in firms’ earnings on evolutionary outcomes. (A) b = 0.5. (B) b = 2.

Figure 7
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 7. Impact of changes in employee losses on evolutionary outcomes. (A) d = 0.5. (B) d = 3.5.

4 Game conclusion

The game analysis of the interaction between employees’ deviant innovation and enterprises’ organizational innovation performance provides us with profound insights into the complex relationship between employees’ deviant innovation behaviors and enterprises’ organizational innovation performance. It is initially found that when the enterprise actively improves organizational innovation performance and the employees implement deviant innovation behaviors, both sides of the game are positive, which maximizes the interests of the enterprise; when the enterprise actively improves organizational innovation performance but the employees do not implement deviant innovation behaviors, the enterprise’s earnings are relatively reduced while the employee’s earnings are affected by the environment to a certain extent; when the enterprise negatively improves organizational innovation performance but the employees implement deviant innovation behaviors, it may lead to the escalation of task conflict and the increase in the number of employees. When the enterprise negatively improves the organizational innovation performance but the employees carry out the deviant innovation behavior, it may lead to the possibility or degree of task conflict escalation into emotional conflict increases, then the employees in the psychological loss will be increased accordingly, which may lead to the employees to choose a more conservative strategy, that is to say, the enterprise negatively improves the organizational innovation performance, the employees do not carry out the deviant innovation behavior of the undesirable locking state. In order to maximize the interests of both enterprises and employees, this paper proposes relevant measures based on the game results.

From the enterprise perspective, companies need to manage this interaction wisely, as this interactive game is one of the key factors for organizational success. Firstly, it is essential to define organizational performance goals, requiring thoughtful and effective strategic planning to ensure rational resource allocation [14]. If companies fail to provide sufficient resources for organizational innovation performance at the outset, employees may feel a lack of support, resulting in the failure of innovation activities. Secondly, fostering an open, inclusive, and innovative cultural atmosphere, establishing efficient innovation teams, and motivating employees’ deviant innovation behavior are crucial [15]. Thirdly, scientific management is required to facilitate positive interactions among employees. When employees actively engage in deviant innovation, companies can leverage their employees’ efforts to adjust their strategies to better respond to market demands. This includes enhancing products, services, or processes to meet evolving customer expectations [16]. Companies can thus adapt more rapidly to market dynamics, thereby enhancing organizational innovation performance.

From the employee perspective, proactive implementation of deviant innovation behavior by responsible employees is crucial [17]. Employees’ deviant innovation behavior can inspire other members within the organization, meaning that when one employee demonstrates courage and innovation capability, other members may be encouraged to actively participate in innovation activities. This internal motivation can significantly contribute to the improvement of organizational innovation performance, thereby enhancing internal cohesion within the company. However, deviant innovation should be controlled within a reasonable range, as only moderate deviant innovation is suitable for the long-term development of the enterprise.

To sum up, the interactive game between employees’ deviant innovation behavior and enterprises’ enhancement of organizational innovation performance is a complex and important theme. Employees’ positive deviant innovation behavior can stimulate the enthusiasm within the organization, and at the same time can help the enterprise to better cope with the market challenges. Organizations need to manage this interaction intelligently to ensure that resources are allocated appropriately to achieve optimal innovation performance. This interactive game is one of the key factors for organizational success and requires thoughtful and effective strategic planning. Only by running in the same direction, employees and organizations will work together to reach higher peaks of innovation.

Data availability statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author contributions

HZ: Conceptualization, Methodology, Writing–original draft, Writing–review and editing. JL: Data curation, Software, Validation, Writing–original draft, Writing–review and editing. YC: Data curation, Software, Validation, Writing–review and editing. YG: Writing–review and editing. ZZ: Writing–review and editing.

Funding

The authors declare financial support was received for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. This research was funded by The National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant numbers 72072076 and 72372106, National Social Science Foundation of China, grant number 19BGL127.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

The handling editor DH declared a shared affiliation with the authors HZ and YC at the time of review.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

1. Zhang LY, Wu MY, Li SY, Liu R, Zhu Y. Exploring the dynamics of role transition of employees in family businesses through the evolutionary game theory. Front Phys (2023) 11:1295646. doi:10.3389/fphy.2023.1295646

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

2. Zhang Q, Zhang HF. A study on the impact of employee's constructive deviant behavior on their innovation performance based on the perspective of manager's meaning construction. J Xidian Univ (2023) 33(04):30–46.

Google Scholar

3. Jiang Y. A review of research on employee transgressive innovation behavior and its prospects. Sci Tech Management Res (2018) 38(10):131–9. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1000-7695.2018.10.018

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

4. Ye CJ, Liu AL. Leaders' bottom-line mindfulness and employees' transgressive innovation-a moderated mediation mode. Sci Tech Management Res (2023) 43(12):176–82. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1000-7695.2023.12.020

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

5. Li YZ. The impact of transformational leadership on employee innovation behavior. The role of psychological empowerment and emotional commitment. Res Management (2018) 39(07):123–30. doi:10.19571/j.cnki.1000-2995.2018.07.015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

6. Kai-Ineman DANIEL, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica (1979) 47(2):363–91. doi:10.2307/1914185

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

7. Smith JM. Evolution and the theory of games. In: Did Darwin get it right? Essays on games, sex and evolution. Boston, MA: Springer US (1982). p. 202–15.

Google Scholar

8. Amir R, Evstigneev VI, Schenk-Hoppé KR. Asset market games of survival: a synthesis of evolutionary and dynamic games. Annals of Finance (2013) 9(2):121–144. doi:10.1007/s10436-012-0210-5

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

9. Eid MS, El-Adaway IH, Coatney KT, Evolutionary stable strategy for postdisaster insurance: game theory approach. J Management Eng (2015) 31(6):04015005. doi:10.1061/(asce)me.1943-5479.0000357

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

10. Feng M, Hu YF. A cross-level study of job stressors on employees' breakthrough and progressive creativity. J Management (2021) 18(07):1012–21. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1672-884x.2021.07.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

11. Welbourne TM, Johnson DE, Erez A. The role-based performance scale: validity analysis of a theory-based measure. Acad Manag J (1998) 41(5):540–55. doi:10.5465/256941

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

12. Wang L, Schuetz CG, Cai D. Choosing response strategies in social media crisis communication: an evolutionary game theory perspective. Inf Management (2021) 58(6):103371. doi:10.1016/j.im.2020.103371

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

13. Friedman D. Evolutionary games in economics. Econometrica (1991) 59:637–66. doi:10.2307/2938222

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

14. Du PC, Fan MJ, Liu SY. The effect of job remodeling on employees' adaptive performance under the perspective of information processing theory. J Capital Univ Econ Business (2022) 24(02):101–12. doi:10.13504/j.cnki.issn1008-2700.2022.02.008

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

15. Roland Michel Déprez G, Battistelli A, Boudrias JS, Cangialosi N. Constructive deviance and proactive behaviors: two distinct approaches to change and innovation in the workplace. Le travail humain (2020) 83(3):235–67. doi:10.3917/th.833.0235

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

16. Wong SI, Kuvaas B. The empowerment expectation–perception gap: an examination of three alternative models. Hum Resource Management J (2018) 28(2):272–87. doi:10.1111/1748-8583.12177

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

17. Zhang H, Liu SP. Transformational leadership, employee responsibility and transgressive innovation behavior. J Southwest Univ Polit Sci L (2020) 22(02):140–51. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1008-4355.2020.02.12

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: deviant innovation behavior, organizational innovation performance, evolutionary game, numerical experiment, undesirable locking state

Citation: Zheng H, Lu J, Chen Y, Gu Y and Zheng Z (2024) A game study on the impact of employees’ deviant innovation behaviors on firms’ organizational innovation performance. Front. Phys. 12:1364550. doi: 10.3389/fphy.2024.1364550

Received: 02 January 2024; Accepted: 09 April 2024;
Published: 06 May 2024.

Edited by:

Dun Han, Jiangsu University, China

Reviewed by:

Jinlong Ma, Hebei University of Science and Technology, China
Yuhao Feng, Beijing University of Posts and Telecommunications (BUPT), China

Copyright © 2024 Zheng, Lu, Chen, Gu and Zheng. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Jie Lu, NjAzNTEzNTc1QHFxLmNvbQ==

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.