Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Phys., 27 October 2021
Sec. Social Physics
This article is part of the Research Topic The paradigm of complexity and the real data of Socio-Economy View all 5 articles

Structure and Evolution of the International Pesticide Trade Networks

Jian-An LiJian-An Li1Wen-Jie Xie,
Wen-Jie Xie1,2*Wei-Xing Zhou,,Wei-Xing Zhou1,2,3
  • 1School of Business, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, China
  • 2Research Center for Econophysics, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, China
  • 3School of Mathematics, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, China

To meet the increasing demand for food around the world, pesticides are widely used and will continue to be widely used in agricultural production to reduce yield losses and maintain product quality. International pesticide trade serves to reallocate the distribution of pesticides around the world. We investigate the statistical properties of the international trade networks of five categories of pesticides from the view angle of temporal directed and weighted networks. We observed an overall increasing trend in network size, network density, average in- and out-degrees, average in- and out-strengths, temporal similarity, and link reciprocity, indicating that the rising globalization of pesticides trade is driving the networks denser. However, the distributions of link weights remain unchanged along time for the five categories of pesticides. In addition, all the networks are disassortatively mixed because large importers or exporters are more likely to trade with small exporters or importers. We also observed positive correlations between in-degree and out-degree, in-strength and out-strength, link reciprocity and in-degree, out-degree, in-strength, and out-strength, while node’s local clustering coefficient is negatively related to in-degree, out-degree, in-strength, and out-strength. We show that some structural and dynamic properties of the international pesticide trade networks are different from those of the international trade networks, highlighting the presence of idiosyncratic features of different goods and products in the international trade.

1 Introduction

The past decades after the World War II have witnessed a marked growth in food production and the total population of the world, together with a dramatic decrease in the proportion of the world’s people that are hungry, and the global demand for food will continuously increase in the coming decades [1, 2]. Seeds, fertilizers, and pesticides, as major agricultural inputs, will continue to play a central role in raising agricultural yields and product quality to meet the challenge of feeding billions of people. Pesticides are widely used in agricultural production around the world to reduce yield losses and maintain product quality by controlling pests, weeds, and other plant pathogens, which has long raised serious concerns about risks to human health and the environment [38]. Nevertheless, the current need to increase food production to feed a rapidly growing population puts pressure on the intensive use of pesticides and thus drives the international trade of pesticides.

International pesticide trade serves to reallocate the distribution of pesticides around the world and forms complex networks. Indeed, the structure and dynamics of the international trade networks as a whole have been extensively studied [919], and researchers have proposed dynamic models to understand the formation of the international trade networks [20, 21], such as the fitness model [22], the gravity model [23, 24], and the enhanced gravity model [25]. There are also studies on the international trade networks of agricultural goods and products. For instance, Gephart and Pace investigated the structure and evolution of the global seafood trade network [26], and Qiang et al studied the evolution of the global agricultural trade network of eight groups of agricultural products [27], and Dupas, Halloy, and Chatzimpiros focused on the dynamics and invariant sub-network structures in the world cereals trade [28]. Furthermore, Wu and Guclu developed a social network model of the global trade of maize to analyze the network patterns and to determine the vulnerable exporters in food security [29], Gephart et al. investigated the vulnerability to shocks in the global seafood trade network [30], and Distefano et al. unveiled shock transmission in the international food trade network [31]. The international trade of food goods and products are associated with a virtual transfer of water resources from production to consumption regions through a network of trade, and the international virtual water networks have also been studied extensively [3240].

However, the international trade networks of agricultural inputs (seeds, fertilizers, and pesticides) are rarely studied. In this work, we investigate the structure and evolution of the international pesticide trade networks (iPTNs) from the view angle of temporal directed and weighted networks. We take into consideration the directions and weights of the links, which are crucial traits of the iPTNs. Specifically, we investigate the evolution of total trade value, network size, network density, overall in- and out-degrees of nodes, overall in- and out-strengths of nodes, four measures of assortativity, network structure stability, reciprocity, and clustering coefficient, as well as the relationships between some pairs of these network metrics. We find that, although most of the structural properties of the international pesticide trade networks are qualitatively similar to those of the whole international trade network, there are also qualitative and quantitative differences, indicating the presence of idiosyncratic features of different goods and products in the international trade. It is thus necessary to explore such disaggregated networks to uncover idiosyncratic properties and dynamics of the international trade networks of specific goods and products.

The remainder of study is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data sets used in our analysis and the construction of the international pesticide trade networks. Section 3 presents the evolution of total trade value, network size, and network density. Section 4 studies the properties of node degrees, link weights, and node strengths. Section 5 investigates the structural patterns of the iPTNs by looking into the similarity of temporal directed networks, the mixing patterns, the reciprocity, and the clustering coefficients. We conclude in Section 6.

2 Data Sets and Network Construction

2.1 Data Description

The data sets analyzed in this work were retrieved from the UN Comtrade database1. The goods about pesticides are under Heading 3808, which contains insecticides, rodenticides, fungicides, herbicides, anti-sprouting products, plant growth regulators, disinfectants, and the like, being put up in forms or packings for retail sale or as preparations or articles. We do not consider the goods with the HS codes being 380852, 380859, 380861, 380862, and 380869 since they have a rather short history. We analyze five categories of pesticides including insecticides (380891), fungicides (380892), herbicides (380893), disinfectants (380894), and rodenticides and other similar products (380899). The data sets available span from 2007 to 2018. Since the data for the year 2019 are incomplete, we use the data from 2007 to 2018.

2.2 Network Construction

Since the trade quantities or net weights of some trades are missing in the UN Comtrade database and are not comparable, we use trade values (US$) of the goods in our investigation. If the trade value of pesticide goods (with HS Code code) exported from economy i to economy j in year t is wijcode(t), the temporal international pesticide trade network is

Wcode(t)=wijcode(t),(1)

where code ∈ {380891, 380892, 380893, 380894, 380899} is the HS codes of the pesticide under investigation and wiicode(t)=0 for all goods in all years. Since a trade might be reported by both exporting and importing economies i and j usually with different values, we use the large value as wijcode(t). There are missing partners and non-economy partners (WLD and EU2), which are not considered in our analysis except noted otherwise. We stress that isolated nodes that do not have any trades with other nodes are not included in the networks. Hence, the economies involved are nodes of the trade network, and a directed link eij is formed if economy i exports to economy j whose weight is wii.

Figure 1 illustrates the international pesticide trade networks for the five goods with codes 380891, 380892, 380893, 380894, and 380899 from top to bottom. For each good, we plot the links with high (98–100%), medium (49–51%), and low (0–2%) trade values of 2% and compare the two networks in 2007 and in 2018. It is observed that the network for each good shows persistence and structural changes.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. International pesticide trade networks. The left and right columns correspond to 2007 and 2018. The rows from top to bottom show the goods with codes 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products). In each map, we show the links with high, medium, and low trade values of 2%.

3 Global Network Features

3.1 Network Size and Number of Links

The size of a network is usually quantified by the number of nodes in the network, NV, where V is the set of nodes. Figure 2A shows the evolution of NV for the five networks. It is observed that the network sizes exhibit an increasing trend decorated with local fluctuations. We can also use the number of links, NE, as the size metric for the network, where E={eij} is the set of links. Figure 2B shows the evolution of NE for the five networks. It is observed that the network sizes increased first and then decreased. In the increasing stage, the increasing trend of the network size flattened along time.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. Evolution of network size and number of links of the five international pesticide trade networks with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) from 2007 to 2018. The network size is quantified by the number of nodes NV in (A) or the number of links NE in (B).

In Figure 3, we also investigate the numbers of exporting and importing economies of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018, denoted by NVex and NVim, respectively. Comparing NVex and NVim in Figure 3 with NV in Figure 2A, we find that

NVex<NVim<NV.(2)

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. Numbers of exporting and importing economies of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. (A) NVex for exporters. (B) NVim for importers. The five codes are 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products).

Hence, there are much more importing economies than exporting economies. On average, the numbers of importing and exporting economies increased along time, but the increasing speed slowed down especially for exporting economies.

3.2 Total Trade Value

The total trade value of a given goods code is

Wcode(t)=i=1NVj=1NVwijcode(t),(3)

which is a value less than the actual value since we do not consider the trade data whose importing or exporting economies are not labeled in the UN Comtrade database. Figure 4A presents the evolution of the international trade values W(t) of the five pesticides from 2007 to 2018. We find that the W(t) curves show an overall rising trend and experienced a fall after rise in 2015. In each year, herbicides (380893) have the largest international trade value, while disinfectants (380894) and rodenticides (380899) have the much lower international trade values.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. (A) Evolution of the total international trade values W(t) (Billion US$) of the five categories of pesticides from 2007 to 2018. (B) Evolution of the average international trade values W(t) (Billion US$) of the five categories of pesticides from 2007 to 2018. The five codes are 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products).

The average international trade value of a given goods code with respect to the number of links is calculated as follows:

Wcode(t)=Wcode(t)NEcode(t),(4)

which is illustrated in Figure 4B. The average international trade value for each pesticide category also shows a rising trend, with a local drop since 2015.

3.3 Network Density

The density of a directed network is the ratio of the number of existing links to the number of links of the complete directed network

ρ=NENV(NV1),(5)

where the complete directed network has NV(NV1) directed links since there are two reciprocal links between each pair of nodes. The evolution of network density ρ is shown in Figure 5. It is found that the shapes of the density curves are similar to the NE curves in Figure 2B, which is rational because NV varies slowly and thus according to Eq. 5, the density ρ is approximately proportional to NE. However, the order of network densities is different from that of the number of links. The insecticides (380891) networks are the most dense, and the disinfectants (380894) networks are also relatively dense. This discrepancy is due to the fact that we do not include in the networks the “inactive” economies that do not have a trade relationship with any other economies, and thus, the number of nodes NVcode(t) is different for different goods in different years. The densities of the pesticides networks are much smaller than those of the international trade networks (around 0.6) [14], which are natural since the international trade networks contain many more goods and thus more links.

FIGURE 5
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 5. Evolution of the network density of the five pesticide goods with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) from 2007 to 2018.

4 Features of Nodes and Links

In this section, we investigate the features of nodes and links, including node in-degree and out-degree, link strength or link weight, and node in-strength and out-strength.

4.1 Node In-Degree and Out-Degree

The in-degree of node jV is defined as follows:

kjin=iV{j}wij0=i=1NVwij0,(6)

where we pose 00 = 0. Similarly, the out-degree of node iV is defined as follows:

kiout=jV{i}wij0=i=1NVwij0.(7)

The average in-degree of nodes (iV) is expressed as follows:

kinV=1NVj=1NVkjin=1NVi=1NVj=1NVwij0,(8)

The average out-degree of nodes (iV) is expressed as follows:

koutV=1NVi=1NVkiout=1NVi=1NVj=1NVwij0.(9)

Since

NE=i=1NVj=1NVwij0,(10)

we have

kinV=koutV=NENV(11)

and

kV=kin+koutV=2NENV.(12)

In Figures 6A–E, we plot in loglog scales the in-degree kiin and out-degree kiout for the five pesticide goods over the period from 2007 to 2018. An economy i has more export partners than import partners if kiout>kiin, which locates above the dashed diagonal in the plots. There is a positive correlation between in-degree and out-degree, which means that an economy that has many (or few) importing partners is more likely to have many (or few) exporting partners. In addition, for each category of pesticides, we can observe the presence of a power law, especially when the number of importing economies (kin) is not too small.

FIGURE 6
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 6. (A–E) Relationship between the in-degree kiin and out-degree kiout for the five pesticide goods with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) over the period from 2007 to 2018. (F) Yearly evolution of the average in-degree over all nodes from 2007 to 2018.

In Figure 6F, we digest the evolution of the average in-degree kinν from 2007 to 2018. We observe that the average in-degree increased first and then experienced a decline. We also find that the shapes of the average in-degree curves are similar to the NE curves in Figure 2B and to the density curves in Figure 5, which is rational because NV varies slowly, and thus, according to Eq. 11, the average in-degree kinν is approximately proportional to NE.

4.2 Weight Distribution

In order to obtain the empirical distribution density f (w) of link weights w, we use logarithmic binning. Equivalently, we determine the empirical distribution g (log 10w) of log 10w through linear binning. The two distributions are related as follows [41].

f(w)dw=g(lnw)dlnw.(13)

It follows that

f(w)=1wg(lnw).(14)

Hence, we first obtain the distribution density g (ln w) of ln w. We show in Figure 7 the distributions of link weights for the five pesticide goods. The most intriguing feature is that, for each pesticide goods, the 12 empirical distributions for the 12 years collapse on the same curve. The distributions for the insecticides (380891) networks in Figure 7A, the fungicides (380892) networks in Figure 7B, and the herbicides (380893) networks in Figure 7C exhibit a power-law scaling when the weights are not large, followed by a faster decay when the weights become larger. There is also a bimodal pattern for the fungicides (380892) networks in Figure 7B and the herbicides (380893) networks in Figure 7C, reminiscent of the bimodal distribution of some social networks [4244]. The distributions for the disinfectants (380894) networks in Figure 7D and the rodenticides (380899) networks in Figure 7E do not show an evident power law. These distributions also exhibit differences from that for the international trade network [45].

FIGURE 7
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 7. Empirical distributions of link weights for the five pesticides trade networks: (A) 380891 for insecticides (A), 380892 for fungicides (B), 380893 for herbicides (C), 380894 for disinfectants (D), and 380899 for rodenticides and other similar products (E). In each plot, there are 13 distributions corresponding to the 13 years.

4.3 Node In-Strength and Out-Strength

The total import value of an economy iV is known as the in-strength of node i in network science, which is defined as follows:

siin=jV{i}wji1=j=1NVwji1,(15)

where we note that wjj = 0. Similarly, the export value of an economy iV is known as the out-strength of node iV is defined as follows:

siout=jV{i}wij1=i=1NVwij1,(16)

The average in-strength of nodes (iV) is expressed as follows:

sinV=1NVj=1NVsjin=1NVi=1NVj=1NVwij1=WNV,(17)

where the last equality is obtained according to Eq. 3. Similarly, the average out-strength of nodes is expressed as follows:

soutV=1NVi=1NVsiout=1NVi=1NVj=1NVwij1=WNV.(18)

Therefore, we have

sinV=soutV=WNV(19)

and

sV=sin+soutV=2WNV.(20)

In Figures 8A–E, we plot in loglog scales the in-strength siin and out-strength siout for the five pesticide goods over the period from 2007 to 2018. We observe that there is a powerlaw relationship

soutsinαs(21)

with αs ≈ 2.5. An economy i has more exports than imports if siout>siin, which locates above the dashed diagonal in the plots. We find that most economies locate below the diagonal, which are import-oriented. It means that the in-strength and out-strength of the pesticide networks are positively correlated. It is different from the case of the whole international trade network, where the in- and out-strengths are almost not correlated with a correlation coefficient of 0.09 being not significantly different from zero [45]. Figure 8F shows the evolution of the average in-degree over all nodes from 2007 to 2018.

FIGURE 8
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 8. (A–E) Relationship between the in-strength siin and out-strength siout for the five pesticide goods with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) over the period from 2007 to 2018. (F) Yearly evolution of the average in-strength over all nodes from 2007 to 2018.

5 Structural Patterns

5.1 Similarity of Temporal Networks

In order to compare the structural stability of two successive networks at t and t + 1, we calculate the similarity coefficient of temporal networks. Let E(t1)t=E(t1)E(t) be the union set of directed links and E(t1)t=E(t1)E(t) be the intersection of directed links in two successive networks G(t1) and G(t). The similarity coefficient between two successive networks G(t1) and G(t) is defined as the ratio of the number of overlapping directed links in the two networks, and the number of all directed links appeared in the two networks:

S(t)=E(t1)tE(t1)t.(22)

where X represents the cardinal number of set X. The similarity coefficient S (t) takes a value in [0, 1]. When the two networks have exactly the same set of directed links, that is, E(t1)=E(t), we have S(t) = 1. When the two networks have no directed links in common, that is, E(t1)t=, we have S(t) = 0. The similarity coefficient defined here is not the same as the temporal correlation coefficient [4648], which is an average of temporal correlation coefficients of nodes in successive networks.

Figure 9A shows the evolution of the temporal similarity coefficient S (t) between two successive networks of the five pesticide goods from 2007 to 2018. We find that the temporal similarity increased first and reached a relatively stable level. The fungicides (380892) trade networks have the highest temporal similarity. Intuitively, we conjecture that links with large weights are more temporally stable. We calculate the similarity coefficients of sub-networks containing small links with the weights less than the 20% percentile, medium links with the weights between the 40 and 60% percentiles, and large links with the weights greater than the 80% percentile. The results are shown in Figures 9B–D, respectively, which verify that the large international trade relationships are more stable than the small international trade relationships.

FIGURE 9
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 9. Evolution of the temporal similarity coefficient S(t) between two successive networks of the five pesticide goods with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) from 2007 to 2018. (A) All links. (B) Small links with the weights less than the 20% percentile. (C) Medium links with the weights between the 40 and 60% percentiles. (D) Large links with the weights greater than the 80% percentile.

5.2 Mixing Pattern

Mixing patterns of links in undirected networks have been introduced and widely studied to quantify the correlation relationship (assortative or disassortative) between node degrees [49, 50], which can be extended to direct networks [51]. From the perspective of trade relationship from exporting economy i to importing economy j, described by link eij, the exporting economy i has an in-degree kiin and an out-degree kiout, and the importing economy j has an in-degree kjin and an out-degree kjout. Hence, associated with the link set E, we have four sequences of the same length NE: in-degree sequence of exporting economies {kiin}, out-degree sequence of exporting economies {kiout}, in-degree sequence of importing economies {kjin}, and out-degree sequence of importing economies {kjout}. Note that, the in-degree sequences {kiin} and {kjin} of exporting and importing economies are not necessarily identical, and out-degree sequences {kiout} and {kjout} of exporting and importing economies are not necessarily identical either. The mean in-degree of exporting economies is

kiinE=1NEeijEkiin,(23)

with the variance being

σi,Ein2=1NEeijEkiinkiinE2,(24)

The mean in-degree of importing economies is

kjinE=1NEeijEkjin(25)

with the variance being

σj,Ein2=1NEeijEkjinkjinE2,(26)

The mean out-degree of exporting economies is

kioutE=1NEeijEkiout(27)

with the variance being

σi,Eout2=1NEeijEkioutkioutE2,(28)

and the mean out-degree of importing economies is

kjoutE=1NEeijEkjout(29)

with the variance being

σj,Eout2=1NEeijEkjoutkjoutE2.(30)

Figure 10 shows the yearly evolution of the average in-degree and out-degree of the exporting and importing economies over all the links. Comparing Figure 10A and Figure 10D, we find that

kiinE=kjoutE,(31)

which can be proved. For each exporting economy i, it has kiout out-links such that

kiinE=1NEeijEkiin=1NEiVexkioutkiin=1NEvVkvoutkvin,(32)

where Vex is the set of all exporting economies. The last equality holds since non-exporting economies do not have out-links, that is, kvout=0 for vVex. Similarly, for each importing economy j, it has kjin any in-links such that

kjoutE=1NEeijEkjout=1NEjVimkjoutkjin=1NEvVkvoutkvin,(33)

where Vim is the set of all importing economies. The last equality holds since non-importing economies do not have any in-links, that is, kvin=0 for vVim.

FIGURE 10
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 10. Yearly evolution of the average in-degree and out-degree of the exporting and importing economies over all the links. The five codes are 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products). (A) Average in-degree of exporting nodes. (B) Average out-degree of exporting nodes. (C) Average in-degree of importing nodes. (D) Average out-degree of importing nodes.

One can define the set of assortativity measures using the Pearson correlation [51]. Specifically, the degree assortative coefficient rin,in(t) between the in-degree of exporting economies and the in-degree of importing economies is

rin,in(t)=1NEeijEkiinkiinEkjinkjinEσi,Einσj,Ein,(34)

The degree assortative coefficient rin,out (t) between the in-degree of exporting economies and the out-degree of importing economies is

rin,out(t)=1NEeijEkiinkiinEkjoutkjoutEσi,Einσj,Eout,(35)

The degree assortative coefficient rout,in (t) between the out-degree of exporting economies and the in-degree of importing economies is

rout,in(t)=1NEeijEkioutkioutEkjinkjinEσi,Eoutσj,Ein,(36)

and the degree assortative coefficient rout,out (t) between the out-degree of exporting economies and the out-degree of importing economies is

rout,out(t)=1NEeijEkioutkioutEkjoutkjoutEσi,Eoutσj,Eout.(37)

Figure 11 illustrates the evolution of the degree assortative coefficients of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. It is found that all the correlation coefficients are negative, showing that the networks are disassortatively mixed. In disassortative international pesticide trade networks, high-degree nodes tend to connect to low-degree nodes, which limit the effects of node failure and relieve the propagation of shocks because important nodes (with many links) are isolated from each other [52]. On average, the degree assortative coefficient rout,in (t) between the out-degree of exporting economies and the in-degree of importing economies is the most negative. We also find that the four-degree assortative coefficients seem more negative in the years 2007 and 2015, compared to the coefficients in other years. We note that the international trade network is also disassortative and the assortativity coefficient (about −0.4) is smaller [14], where the link directions are not considered.

FIGURE 11
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 11. Evolution of degree assortative coefficients of the five international pesticide trade networks with the codes being 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products) from 2007 to 2018. (A) The degree assortative coefficient rin,in (t) between the in-degree of exporting economies and the in-degree of importing economies. (B) The degree assortative coefficient rin,out (t) between the in-degree of exporting economies and the out-degree of importing economies. (C) The degree assortative coefficient rout,in (t) between the out-degree of exporting economies and the in-degree of importing economies. (D) The degree assortative coefficient rout,out (t) between the out-degree of exporting economies and the out-degree of importing economies.

5.3 Reciprocity

The reciprocity of a directed network is defined as the ratio of the number of bilateral links (i.e., links pointing in both directions) to the total number of links in the network [9, 22], that is,

R=(i,j): eijE&ejiE(i,j): eijE=1NEiVkiR,(38)

where

kiR=j: eijE&ejiE=jiwijwji0(39)

is the reciprocal degree of node i so that

(i,j):eijE&ejiE=iVkiR.(40)

The reciprocity coefficient is also known as the percentage of bilateral links [14].

Figure 12 shows the evolution of overall reciprocity of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. It is found that the overall reciprocity coefficients are all greater than 0.32. It is found that the overall reciprocity was stable before 2014 and increased slightly afterward. In addition, the overall reciprocity coefficients are abnormally greater than its neighbor years, especially for pesticide goods 380891, 380892, and 380893. The reciprocity coefficients of the pesticides networks are much smaller than those of the international trade networks (around 0.9) [14], which are natural since the international trade networks contain many more goods and thus more reciprocal links.

FIGURE 12
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 12. Evolution of overall reciprocity of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. The five codes are 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products).

The reciprocity of a single node i is defined similarly, and it is the ratio of the number of links in both directions to the total number of links attached to node i:

Ri=j:eijE&ejiEj:eijEorejiE=kiRki.(41)

We calculate the reciprocity coefficients Ri of economies in each network and compare them with the in-degree kiin and out-degree kiout as well as the in-strength siin and out-strength siout of the corresponding economies. The results for the international insecticides (380891) networks are shown in Figure 13. The results are similar for other four categories of pesticides. We find that for each network, the node reciprocity coefficients are distributed broadly, spanning from 0 (pure import or export economies) to 1 (economies that have both import and export relationships with each trade partner). The economies with Ri = 1 are leaf nodes with a pair of reciprocal links because they have kiin=1 and kiout=1 as shown in Figures 13A,B while their import and export values are not large as shown in Figure 13C and Figure 13D. Excluding data points with R = 0 or R = 1, we observe an linearly increasing relationship between reciprocity Ri and logarithmic trade values siin and siout. In other words, an economy with a large import or/and export value will have a large reciprocity coefficient. In addition, the slope is larger for kiin in Figure 13A and siin in Figure 13C than kiout in Figure 13B and siout in Figure 13D.

FIGURE 13
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 13. Scatter plots of the reciprocity coefficients of economies in the insecticides (380891) network with respect to the corresponding node attributes. (A) Reciprocity coefficient Ri versus in-degree kiin. (B) Reciprocity coefficient Ri versus out-degree kiout. (C) Reciprocity coefficient Ri versus in-strength siin. (D) Reciprocity coefficient Ri versus out-strength siout.

5.4 Clustering Coefficient

For unweighted graphs, the clustering of a node i is the fraction of possible triangles through that node that exist,

ci=2Tiki(ki1),(42)

where Ti is the number of triangles through node u and ki is the degree of i. For weighted networks, there are several ways to define the clustering coefficient [53, 54]. For directed graphs, the clustering is similarly defined as the fraction of all possible directed triangles or geometric average of the subgraph link weights for unweighted and weighted directed network, respectively [45]:

ci=2Tiki(ki1)2kiR,(43)

where Ti is the number of directed triangles through node i, ki=kiin+kiin is the sum of in-degree and out-degree of i, and kiR is the reciprocal degree of i. The overall clustering coefficient of a network is the average of the clustering coefficients of all nodes, that is,

C=1NVi=1NVci.(44)

Figure 14 shows the evolution of the overall clustering coefficients of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. For the insecticides (380891) network and the rodenticides (380899) network, the overall clustering coefficient C(t) curves exhibit a U-shape. For the disinfectants (380894) network, the C(t) curve has an increasing trend. For the rest two networks, the C(t) curves fluctuate stably, and the curve for the fungicides (380892) network has an evident local maximum at the year 2015. It is not surprising that the international trade networks have higher clustering coefficients close to 0.82 [14].

FIGURE 14
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 14. Evolution of overall clustering coefficients of the five international pesticide trade networks from 2007 to 2018. The five codes are 380891 (insecticides), 380892 (fungicides), 380893 (herbicides), 380894 (disinfectants), and 380899 (rodenticides and other similar products).

We show the scatter plots of the clustering coefficients ci of nodes in the insecticides (380891) network with respect to the in-degree kiin in Figure 15A and the out-degree kiout in Figure 15B. The results for other pesticide networks are similar. When the degrees (kiin and kiout) are not too small, the clustering coefficient ci shows a decreasing trend, indicating that economies with less trade partners are more likely to form local denser clusters. In addition, we observe a more evident decreasing trend in Figure 15B than in Figure 15A. These patterns are similar to the whole international trade network, where the correlation between the clustering coefficient and node degree is negative [14].

FIGURE 15
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 15. Scatter plots of the clustering coefficients of economies in the insecticides (380891) network with respect to the corresponding node attributes. (A) Clustering coefficient ci versus in-degree kiin. (B) Clustering coefficient ci versus out-degree kiout. (C) Clustering coefficient ci versus in-strength siin. (D) Clustering coefficient ci versus out-strength siout.

We also show the scatter plots of the clustering coefficients ci of nodes in the insecticide (380891) network with respect to the in-strength siin in Figure 15C and the out-strength siout in Figure 15D. The results for other pesticide networks are similar. It is observed that the economies with a zero clustering coefficient have not too large import and export values (siin<2×106 or siout<106), while the economies with ci = 1 usually have medium import and export values. Excluding the points with ci = 0, we can observe a decreasing trend, which is more evident for siout in Figure 15D. It indicates that economies with smaller trade values are more likely to form local denser clusters.

6 Conclusion

In this study, we have investigated the structure and evolution of the international trade networks of five categories of pesticides including insecticides (380891), fungicides (380892), herbicides (380893), disinfectants (380894), and rodenticides and other similar products (380899) retrieved from the UN Comtrade database. The yearly sampled data sets cover the time period from 2007 to 2018. Specifically, we have explored the global properties including total trade value, network size, and network density, the first-order properties of nodes and links including node degrees, link weights and node strengths, and the structural patterns including temporal similarity, mixing patterns, reciprocity, and the clustering coefficients. Our analyses were carried out from the perspective of temporal weighted and directed network. In particular, taking link directions into consideration allows us to better understand the structure and behavior of international pesticide trade. Certainly, other topics about complex networks like node centrality, group formation, community detection, and link prediction may be useful for future research on the temporal international pesticide trade networks [5560].

We observed an overall increasing trend in almost all global network metrics quantifying the growth and densification of networks, including network size, network density, average in- and out-degrees, average in- and out-strengths, temporal similarity, and link reciprocity. It means that the international pesticide trade networks are becoming more connected. These findings show the continuous integration and globalization of international pesticide trade. However, we also observed that the trend of integration and globalization of international pesticide trade have slowed down in the last decade. Interestingly, we found that the distributions of link weights remain unchanged along time for the five categories of pesticides.

From the directed network perspective, we found that all the networks are disassortatively mixed. It means that large importers or exporters are more likely to trade with small exporters or importers, while the probability of trades between large importers or exporters and between small importers or exporters is relatively low. We also observed positive correlations between in-degree and out-degree, between in-strength and out-strength, between link reciprocity and in-degree, out-degree, and in-strength and out-strength. In contrast, node’s local clustering coefficient is negatively related to in-degree, out-degree, in-strength, and out-strength. It suggests that exporting economies usually produce only some pesticides with an excess volume of production due to their comparative advantages of technology or labor and need to import other pesticides.

Our preliminary analysis shows that, although most of the structural properties of the international pesticide trade networks are qualitatively similar to those of the whole international trade network, we uncovered qualitative and quantitative differences. The quantitative differences mainly come from the fact that the international pesticides networks are only part of the whole international trade network. However, the qualitative differences show the presence of idiosyncratic features of different goods and products in the international trade. Exploration of such disaggregated networks will uncover idiosyncratic properties and dynamics of the international trade networks of specific goods and products.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available datasets were analyzed in this study. This data can be found here: https://comtrade.un.org/data.

Author Contributions

W-JX and W-XZ conceived the research. J-AL analyzed the data and prepared the figures. J-AL and W-XZ analyzed the results and wrote the paper. All authors discussed and reviewed the manuscript.

Funding

This work was partly supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (72171083), the Shanghai Outstanding Academic Leaders Plan, and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Footnotes

1https://comtrade.un.org/data/

References

1. Godfray HCJ, Beddington JR, Crute IR, Haddad L, Lawrence D, Muir JF, et al. Food Security: the challenge of Feeding 9 Billion People. Science (2010) 327:812–8. doi:10.1126/science.1185383

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

2. Tilman D, Balzer C, Hill J, Befort BL. Global Food Demand and the Sustainable Intensification of Agriculture. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A (2011) 108:20260–4. doi:10.1073/pnas.1116437108

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

3. Brethour C, Weersink A. An Economic Evaluation of the Environmental Benefits from Pesticide Reduction. Agric Econ (2001) 25:219–26. doi:10.1111/j.1574-0862.2001.tb00202.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

4. Carvalho FP. Agriculture, Pesticides, Food Security and Food Safety. Environ Sci Pol (2006) 9:685–92. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2006.08.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

5. Cooper J, Dobson H. The Benefits of Pesticides to Mankind and the Environment. Crop Prot (2007) 26:1337–48. doi:10.1016/j.cropro.2007.03.022

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

6. Damalas CA, Eleftherohorinos IG. Pesticide Exposure, Safety Issues, and Risk Assessment Indicators. Int J Environ Res Public Health (2011) 8:1402–19. doi:10.3390/ijerph8051402

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

7. Drogue S, DeMaria F. Pesticide Residues and Trade, the Apple of Discord?Food Policy (2012) 37:641–9. doi:10.1016/j.foodpol.2012.06.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

8. Carvalho FP. Pesticides, Environment, and Food Safety. Food Energy Secur (2017) 6:48–60. doi:10.1002/fes3.108

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

9. Serrano MA, Boguñá M. Topology of the World Trade Web. Phys Rev E (2003) 68:015101. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.68.015101

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

10. Garlaschelli D, Loffredo MI. Structure and Evolution of the World Trade Network. Physica A (2005) 355:138–44. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2005.02.075

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

11. Garlaschelli D, Di Matteo T, Aste T, Caldarelli G, Loffredo MI. Interplay between Topology and Dynamics in the World Trade Web. Eur Phys J B (2007) 57:159–64. doi:10.1140/epjb/e2007-00131-6

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

12. Fagiolo G, Reyes J, Schiavo S. On the Topological Properties of the World Trade Web: A Weighted Network Analysis. Physica A 387 (2008) 3868–73. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2008.01.050

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

13. Fagiolo G, Reyes J, Schiavo S. World-trade Web: Topological Properties, Dynamics, and Evolution. Phys Rev E (2009) 79:036115. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.79.036115

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

14. Fagiolo G, Reyes J, Schiavo S. The Evolution of the World Trade Web: A Weighted-Network Analysis. J Evol Econ (2010) 20:479–514. doi:10.1007/s00191-009-0160-x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

15. Squartini T, Fagiolo G, Garlaschelli D. Randomizing World Trade. I. A Binary Network Analysis. Phys Rev E (2011) 84:046117. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.84.046117

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

16. Squartini T, Fagiolo G, Garlaschelli D. Randomizing World Trade. II. A Weighted Network Analysis. Phys Rev E (2011) 84:046118. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.84.046118

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

17. Karpiarz M, Fronczak P, Fronczak A. International Trade Network: Fractal Properties and Globalization Puzzle. Phys Rev Lett (2014) 113. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.113.248701

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

18. Torreggiani S, Mangioni G, Puma MJ, Fagiolo G. Identifying the Community Structure of the Food-Trade International Multi-Network. Environ Res Lett (2018) 13:054026. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/aabf23

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

19. Campi M, Duenas M, Fagiolo G. How Do Countries Specialize in Agricultural Production? a Complex Network Analysis of the Global Agricultural Product Space. Environ Res Lett (2020) 15:124006. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/abc2f6

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

20. Bhattacharya K, Mukherjee G, Saramäki J, Kaski K, Manna SS. The International Trade Network: Weighted Network Analysis and Modelling. J Stat Mech (2008) P02002. doi:10.1088/1742-5468/2008/02/P02002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

21. Mastrandrea R, Squartini T, Fagiolo G, Garlaschelli D. Reconstructing the World Trade Multiplex: the Role of Intensive and Extensive Biases. Phys Rev E (2014) 90:062804. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.90.062804

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

22. Garlaschelli D, Loffredo M. Patterns of Link Reciprocity in Directed Networks. Phys Rev Lett (2004) 93:268701. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.93.268701

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

23. Fagiolo G. The International-Trade Network: Gravity Equations and Topological Properties. J Econ Interact Coord (2010) 5:1–25. doi:10.1007/s11403-010-0061-y

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

24. Duenas M, Fagiolo G. Modeling the International-Trade Network: a Gravity Approach. J Econ Interact Coord (2013) 8:155–78. doi:10.1007/s11403-013-0108-y

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

25. Almog A, Bird R, Garlaschelli D. Enhanced Gravity Model of Trade: Reconciling Macroeconomic and Network Models. Front Phys (2019) 7:55. doi:10.3389/fphy.2019.00055

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

26. Gephart JA, Pace ML. Structure and Evolution of the Global Seafood Trade Network. Environ Res Lett (2015) 10:125014. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/10/12/125014

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

27. Qiang W, Niu S, Wang X, Zhang C, Liu A, Cheng S. Evolution of the Global Agricultural Trade Network and Policy Implications for China. Sustainability (2020) 12:192. doi:10.3390/su12010192

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

28. Dupas MC, Halloy J, Chatzimpiros P. Time Dynamics and Invariant Subnetwork Structures in the World Cereals Trade Network. PLoS One (2019) 14:e0216318. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0216318

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

29. Wu F, Guclu H. Global maize Trade and Food Security: Implications from a Social Network Model. Risk Anal (2013) 33:2168–78. doi:10.1111/risa.12064

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

30. Gephart JA, Rovenskaya E, Dieckmann U, Pace ML, Braennstroem A. Vulnerability to Shocks in the Global Seafood Trade Network. Environ Res Lett (2016) 11:035008. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/11/3/035008

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

31. Distefano T, Laio F, Ridolfi L, Schiavo S. Shock Transmission in the International Food Trade Network. PLoS One (2018) 13:e0200639. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0200639

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

32. Moederl M, Sitzenfrei R, Fetz T, Fleischhacker E, Rauch W. Systematic Generation of Virtual Networks for Water Supply. Water Resour Res (2011) 47:W02502. doi:10.1029/2009WR008951

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

33. Suweis S, Konar M, Dalin C, Hanasaki N, Rinaldo A, Rodriguez-Iturbe I. Structure and Controls of the Global Virtual Water Trade Network. Geophys Res Lett (2011) 38:L10403. doi:10.1029/2011GL046837

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

34. Dalin C, Konar M, Hanasaki N, Rinaldo A, Rodriguez-Iturbe I. Evolution of the Global Virtual Water Trade Network. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A (2012) 109:5989–94. doi:10.1073/pnas.1203176109

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

35. Carr JA, D’Odorico P, Laio F, Ridolfi L. On the Temporal Variability of the Virtual Water Network. Geophys Res Lett (2012) 39:L06404. doi:10.1029/2012GL051247

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

36. Konar M, Dalin C, Hanasaki N, Rinaldo A, Rodriguez-Iturbe I. Temporal Dynamics of Blue and green Virtual Water Trade Networks. Water Resour Res (2012) 48:W07509. doi:10.1029/2012WR011959

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

37. Dermody BJ, van Beek RPH, Meeks E, Goldewijk KK, Scheidel W, van der Velde Y, et al. A Virtual Water Network of the Roman World. Hydrol Earth Syst Sci (2014) 18:5025–40. doi:10.5194/hess-18-5025-2014

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

38. Tuninetti M, Tamea S, Laio F, Ridolfi L. To Trade or Not to Trade: Link Prediction in the Virtual Water Network. Adv Water Resour (2017) 110:528–37. doi:10.1016/j.advwatres.2016.08.013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

39. Garcia S, Mejia A. Characterizing and Modeling Subnational Virtual Water Networks of US Agricultural and Industrial Commodity Flows. Adv Water Resour (2019) 130:314–24. doi:10.1016/j.advwatres.2019.06.013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

40. Levine B, Nozick L, Jones D. Estimating an Origin-Destination Table for US Imports of Waterborne Containerized Freight. Transp Res E-logist Transp Rev (2009) 45:611–26. doi:10.1016/j.tre.2008.11.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

41. Press W, Teukolsky S, Vetterling W, Flannery B. Numerical Recipes in FORTRAN: The Art of Scientific Computing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1996).

Google Scholar

42. Wu Y, Zhou CS, Xiao JH, Kurths J, Schellnhuber HJ. Evidence for a Bimodal Distribution in Human Communication. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A (2010) 107:18803–8. doi:10.1073/pnas.1013140107

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

43. Jiang ZQ, Xie WJ, Li MX, Podobnik B, Zhou WX, Stanley HE. Calling Patterns in Human Communication Dynamics. Proc Natl Acad Sci U.S.A (2013) 110:1600–5. doi:10.1073/pnas.1220433110

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

44. Li MX, Xiao QL, Wang Y, Zhou WX. Statistical Properties of the Mutual Transfer Network Among Global Football Clubs. Int J Mod Phys B (2018) 32:1850320. doi:10.1142/S0217979218503204

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

45. Fagiolo G. Clustering in Complex Directed Networks. Phys Rev E (2007) 76:026107. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.76.026107

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

46. Tang J, Scellato S, Musolesi M, Mascolo C, Latora V. Small-world Behavior in Time-Varying Graphs. Phys Rev E (2010) 81:055101. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.81.055101

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

47. Buettner K, Salau J, Krieter J. Adaption of the Temporal Correlation Coefficient Calculation for Temporal Networks (Applied to a Real-World Pig Trade Network). SpringerPlus (2016) 5:165. doi:10.1186/s40064-016-1811-7

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

48. Buettner K, Salau J, Krieter J. Temporal Correlation Coefficient for Directed Networks. SpringerPlus (2016) 5:1198. doi:10.1186/s40064-016-2875-0

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

49. Newman M. Assortative Mixing in Networks. Phys Rev Lett (2002) 89:208701. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.89.208701

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

50. Newman M. Mixing Patterns in Networks. Phys Rev E (2003) 67:026126. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.67.026126

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

51. Foster JG, Foster DV, Grassberger P, Paczuski M. Edge Direction and the Structure of Networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A (2010) 107:10815–20. doi:10.1073/pnas.0912671107

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

52. Maslov S, Sneppen K. Specificity and Stability in Topology of Protein Networks. Science (2002) 296:910–3. doi:10.1126/science.1065103

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

53. Onnela JP, Saramäki J, Kertész J, Kaski K. Intensity and Coherence of Motifs in Weighted Complex Networks. Phys Rev E (2005) 71:065103. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.71.065103

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

54. Saramäki J, Kivela M, Onnela JP, Kaski K, Kertész J. Generalizations of the Clustering Coefficient to Weighted Complex Networks. Phys Rev E (2007) 75:027105. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.75.027105

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

55. Bellingeri M, Bevacqua D, Scotognella F, Alfieri R, Cassi D. A Comparative Analysis of Link Removal Strategies in Real Complex Weighted Networks. Sci Rep (2020) 10:3911. doi:10.1038/s41598-020-60298-7

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

56. Wang W, Jiang J, An B, Jiang Y, Chen B. Toward Efficient Team Formation for Crowdsourcing in Noncooperative Social Networks. IEEE T Cybern (2017) 47:4208–22. doi:10.1109/TCYB.2016.2602498

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

57. Jiang J, An B, Jiang Y, Zhang C, Bu Z, Cao J. Group-oriented Task Allocation for Crowdsourcing in Social Networks. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern -Syst (2021) 51:4417–32. doi:10.1109/TSMC.2019.2933327

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

58. Bu Z, Li HJ, Zhang C, Cao J, Li A, Shi Y. Graph K-Means Based on Leader Identification, Dynamic Game, and Opinion Dynamics. IEEE Trans Knowl Data Eng (2020) 32:1348–61. doi:10.1109/TKDE.2019.2903712

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

59. Bu Z, Wang Y, Li HJ, Jiang J, Wu Z, Cao J. Link Prediction in Temporal Networks: Integrating Survival Analysis and Game Theory. Inf Sci (2019) 498:41–61. doi:10.1016/j.ins.2019.05.050

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

60. Cao J, Bu Z, Wang Y, Yang H, Jiang J, Li HJ. Detecting Prosumer-Community Groups in Smart Grids from the Multiagent Perspective. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern -Syst (2019) 49:1652–64. doi:10.1109/TSMC.2019.2899366

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: econophysics, directed networks, weighted networks, network metrics, international pesticide trade networks

Citation: Li J-A, Xie W-J and Zhou W-X (2021) Structure and Evolution of the International Pesticide Trade Networks. Front. Phys. 9:681788. doi: 10.3389/fphy.2021.681788

Received: 17 March 2021; Accepted: 21 September 2021;
Published: 27 October 2021.

Edited by:

Emmanuel E. Haven, Memorial University of Newfoundland, Canada

Reviewed by:

Jie Cao, Nanjing University of Finance and Economics, China
Michele Bellingeri, University of Parma, Italy
Jiuchuan Jiang, Nanjing University of Finance and Economics, China

Copyright © 2021 Li, Xie and Zhou. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Wen-Jie Xie, d2p4aWVAZWN1c3QuZWR1LmNu

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.