Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Environ. Sci., 08 July 2022
Sec. Environmental Economics and Management

Policy Intervention Effect Research on Pesticide Packaging Waste Recycling: Evidence From Jiangsu, China

Naijuan Hu&#x;Naijuan Hu1Qian Zhang&#x;Qian Zhang1Chenglong LiChenglong Li2Hongwu Sun
Hongwu Sun1*
  • 1Institute of Agricultural Economics and Development, Jiangsu Academy of Agricultural Science, Nanjing, China
  • 2College of Economics and Management, Nanjing Agricultural University, Nanjing, China

Large quantities of pesticide packaging wastes have been thrown and abandoned in farmlands and surrounding environments, which is not only difficult to degrade but also posing a potential pollution threat to agricultural produce and the ecological environment due to the high concentration residues of pesticide. The Chinese government has formulated a series of policies and measures and established some recycling pilot provinces. However, the intervention effects of different kinds of policies on pesticide packaging waste recycling by farmers’ and its mechanism were still unknown. This study took the pilot province Jiangsu Province as the example, by using the game theory and propensity score matching (PSM) model to analyze and compare the intervention effects of three kinds of pesticide packaging waste recycling policies, that is, punish, subsidy and reward, and mortgage return. The results showed that the three kinds of policies all positively affected farmers’ recycling behaviors in the pilot area. The incentive effect of the punishment policy was the weakest, and the mortgage return policy was prominent with the recycling probability increasing 44.8% under a single policy. Based on these results, some policy suggestions were put forward as follows: improving farmers’ cognition of environmental pollution caused by pesticide packaging waste and their awareness of environmental protection, establishing the necessary administrative punishment policy, increasing financial support and improving the standard of recycling subsidies, and vigorously promoting the mortgage return recovery policy in areas where conditions permit. So as to stimulate the willingness of pesticide users to recover independently, the government should reduce the cost of administrative law enforcement and contribute to the construction of rural ecological civilization.

1 Introduction

In the past few decades, pesticides have been widely used in agriculture in order to control pests and improve crop yields (Fernandes et al., 2020; Sharma et al., 2020), and it remains a key input factor for global food security at present (Maldani et al., 2017; Bagheri et al., 2018). Nonetheless, farmers tend to overuse pesticides to better control microbial diseases and pests (Bagheri et al., 2018), which is accompanied by the improper treatment of a large number of pesticide packaging waste. Pesticide packaging materials are generally made of polyester bottles and aluminum foil bags, with low economic value of reuse (Jones, 2014; Li and Huang, 2018). However, due to the difficulty of breaking down pesticide packaging waste, it is continuously accumulated in the farmland ecological environment for a long time, forming white pollution and affecting crop growth and agricultural machinery operation (Pasdar et al., 2017; Pirsaheb et al., 2017). Moreover, the high concentrated pesticides left in the packaging can directly enter waters and soils, posing potential hazards and threats to the production safety of agricultural products, rural ecological environment, and human health (Briassoulis et al., 2014; Eras et al., 2017; Marnasidis et al., 2018). A recent study has shown that about 83% of 317 topsoil samples contain 76 different types of pesticide residues from 11 EU countries (Silva et al., 2019). In addition, the Moroccan Poison Control Center reported that there were 1,451 cases of pesticide poisoning in 2015 (Badrane et al., 2018).

In order to minimize the potential harm of pesticide packaging waste, some countries have taken effective measures and established the system of waste pesticide packaging. For example, the non-profit organization for terminal treatment of pesticide packaging waste established in Brazil played an important role in the recycling and treatment of waste pesticide packages. Similar management schemes were established in some European countries, such as Belgium, France, and Germany (FAO/WHO, 2008). These schemes widely introduce the extension of producer responsibility, internalize external costs to pesticide producers, and improve the design of pesticide packaging, so as to increase the recycling efficiency of pesticide packaging waste (Park et al., 2018). The recycling of pesticide packaging waste is a pro-environmental behavior, which is inseparable from the extensive participation of farmers. Although some policies of pesticide packaging waste have been issued in some countries, the effect of farmers’ recycling in most areas was still not ideal. According to the survey of the Rural Economic Research Center of the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs of the People’s Republic of China, more than 62% of pesticide users in China habitually discard pesticide packaging waste in water or farmland and their surrounding areas (Wei and Jin, 2014).

In recent years, many studies have been carried out on farmers’ behavior, attitude, and influencing factors in disposal of pesticide packaging waste (Garbounis and Komilis, 2021; Khadda et al., 2021; Li et al., 2021; Bondori et al., 2019; Li M. Y. et al., 2020). It was found that farmers in northern Greece and Mogan of Iran generally discard empty pesticide containers in farmlands, irrigation channels, and surrounding areas (Damalas et al., 2008; Bondori et al., 2019). Xu et al. (2021) found that the recycling price had the largest relative effect on control waste pesticide bottles based on a two-stage Heckman model in China. Zhao and Zhou, (2021) reported that the subsidy for pesticide packaging waste recycling should be normalized, and the way of incentive and supervision should be taken to improve the recycling enthusiasm of farmers, and Liu et al. (2021) believed that it was necessary to consider formulating differentiated compensation standards according to different pesticide packaging waste recycling schemes. Other researchers attributed the low recycling rate of pesticide packaging wastes to the poor quality of farmers themselves, poor awareness of pesticide risks, high proportion of non-agricultural employment, and inadequate rural recovery facilities (Zyoud et al., 2010; Sun, 2018; Wei and Du, 2018). Although most of the existing studies mainly focused on the influence factors of farmers’ pro-environmental behavior (Botetzagias et al., 2015; Wang Y. D. et al., 2019; Thu et al., 2020; Zhou et al., 2020), few researchers had paid attention to the effect and mechanism of policy implementation on farmers’ pesticide packaging waste recycling behavior.

The direct reason for the low recycling rate of farmers is lack of a behavioral driving force (Zhang et al., 2018; Li Z. M. et al., 2020; Meng et al., 2022). According to the theory of organizational behavior, to enhance the driving force of individual behavior, two kinds of means were generally taken: restraint and incentive, including law enforcement, external policy intervention, and improving market incentive (Hage et al., 2009; Li M. Y. et al., 2020; Pan et al., 2021). Agricultural waste pollution is a typical “external diseconomy” (Ellis and Fellner, 1943). The externality theory holds that an external diseconomy (negative externality) occurs in economic activities if a manufacturer causes losses that do not require payment to other manufacturers or society. At this time, market failure occurs, and the government needs to get involved for appropriate intervention (Abadie et al., 2016; Tang et al., 2021). The recycling of pesticide packaging waste is a beneficial social behavior, and recycling can produce positive externalities of the environment. However, because environmental resources are non-exclusive and non-competitive as public goods, pesticide users can directly benefit from the utilization of environmental resources without paying fees, so they generally make little or no contribution to environmental protection without external economic stimulus. The environmental damage caused by the utilization of environmental resources is finally transferred to the government, thus leading to the conflict between the choice of the government and the choice of farmers. If there are no any intervention measures, collective action will be in a dilemma. Li et al. (2019) believed that it was necessary for the government to take certain incentive or restraint policies to internalize the externality of environmental pollution. Among them, Pigou (1932) emphasized that the government should strengthen the direct regulation of the government by means of taxation and subsidies, which also provided a direct theoretical basis for the government to strengthen environmental regulation. According to the theory of institutional economics, institution is an important condition to restrict the behavior of subjects. In the case of market failure, the system can restrain and stimulate the subject’s behavior through its coercive force and inducement, so as to form stable expectations and reduce transaction costs (Lu, 1996). In addition, existing studies have shown that government policies can effectively promote farmers to adopt the pro-environmental production mode by means of constraints, guidance, and incentives (Ma et al., 2009; Trujillo-Barrera et al., 2016; Brodhagen et al., 2017; Zhang et al., 2018), which laid a foundation for our study to explore how to apply policy measures to transform the externality of pesticide packaging waste recycling into internality.

China has been the largest pesticide user and consumer in the world over several decades, with nearly 1.3 million tons of pesticide consumption in 2020 (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2021), and applies between 1.5 and 4.0 times more pesticides per hectare than the global average (Zhang et al., 2015). At the same time, China consumes more than 3.5 billion pesticide packaging materials every year. With the proposal of ecological civilization, the Chinese government pays more and more attention to the ecological environment, which is a prominent political issue related to the CPC’s mission and a major social problem related to people’s livelihood (Xi, 2019). Agricultural environmental pollution is related to the overall plan of ecological civilization (Zhang, 2019). With the maturity and deepening of scientific research on livestock and poultry manure, agricultural straw, and agricultural film, and the strict implementation of management policies, traditional agricultural non-point source pollution has been treated accordingly (Dai and Dong, 2014; Cao et al., 2020; Wang et al., 2020). Pesticide packaging waste is becoming the focus of agricultural and rural pollution control. China has issued a series of policies for recycling of pesticide packaging waste, and some provinces also have made some explorations in the recycling of pesticide packaging waste (Jin et al., 2018), especially the Soil Pollution Prevention and Control Law of the People’s Republic of China, which was officially implemented on 1 January 2019, stipulates that producers, sellers, and users of agricultural inputs shall timely recycle the packaging waste and agricultural film of farming inputs such as pesticides and fertilizers, and hand over the pesticide packaging waste to particular institutions or organizations for bio-safety disposal. However, so far, China has not established a nationwide pesticide packaging waste recycling system, and there is a lack of unified management regulations or technical guidelines for the recycling of pesticide packaging waste (Wei and Du, 2018).

Jiangsu Province is an important agricultural production base in China, which is located in the middle and lower reaches of the Yangtze River and the transition zone between the north and the south. It has a mild climate, abundant rainfall, concentrated precipitation, significant plum rain, and abundant light and heat. Affected by the mid-latitude sea land facies transition zone and climate transition zone, as well as the westerly zone, subtropical zone, and low latitude easterly zone weather system, meteorological disasters occur frequently, with many types and a wide range of impact, including frequent and repeated diseases and insect pests. In addition, the scattered small-scale agricultural production mode still dominates, and the production scale of vegetables and fruit trees in facility agriculture is still small, mostly between 20 and 30 mu. The frequent occurrence of plant diseases and insect pests demands high requirements for the frequency application of pesticides; thus, the use intensity of pesticides is at a high level in the country, especially there is a large proportion of demand for small packaging pesticides. As one of the five pilot provinces in China, Jiangsu Province has created several intervention policies on pesticide packaging waste recycling, like punish, subsidy and reward, mortgage return, criticism and education, and inspection orders. However, few studies have determined the following questions: whether these policies played an effective role? Are there differences in intervention effects among different policies? Which policy is more feasible and practical? Hence, this study taking Jiangsu as an example, adopted the game theory and propensity score matching (PSM) model to empirically analyze the intervention effect differences and influencing factors of the three typical recovery policies of “punishment,” “subsidy reward,” and “mortgage return” through the field investigation of farmers in some recovery pilot and non-pilot areas. The results, on the one hand, provide an optimal path in screening, optimizing, and popularizing the recycling strategies of pesticide packaging waste for policy makers; on the other hand, they offer a reference for evaluation on the effect of policy implementation.

2 Theoretical Analysis and Research Hypothesis

2.1 Negative Externalities of Pesticide Packaging Waste

The negative externality of pesticide packaging waste is reflected in both the subject of recycling responsibility and other residents. When Farmer A willingly discards pesticide packaging waste, it results in water and soil pollution. A negative externality will damage agricultural product safety and human health and bring welfare loss to Farmer B. In other words, UB (the utility of Farmer B) is a function of Farmer B’s consumption (X1, X2, X3…) and UA (the behavioral utility of Farmer A). It is necessary to internalize the negative externality of pesticide packaging waste pollution caused by Farmer A through a punish or tax system.

UB=g(X1,X2,X3......,UA).

On the contrary, pesticide packaging waste recycling is typical of positive externalities. Still, the beneficiaries of positive externalities are the recyclers themselves, the whole ecosystem, and all residents. The recyclers cannot obtain the revenue equivalent to the positive externalities. Therefore, it’s a stretch to demand farmers to recycle pesticide packaging waste. In addition, farmers need to invest additional labor, material, and financial resources in recycling, which will result in a lack of internal motivation for farmers to recycle. Hence, compensation or other incentive systems enable farmers to obtain benefits equivalent to the positive externality of pesticide packaging waste recycling.

2.2 Analysis of Policy Theoretical Mechanism

At present, waste recycling management strategies mainly include incentive and property right exchange. Incentives are divided into positive incentives and negative incentives. Positive incentives are rewards and subsidies, etc., and negative incentives are punishment and education, etc. The advantages of punishment and return management measures are that the financial pressure of local governments is small, but punishment measures are easy to stimulate people’s inner tendency to be exploited, resulting in negative emotional (Zorpas et al., 2018). In addition, if effective punishment is to be realized, considerable supervision force is required, the requirements for labor, financial, and resources are relatively high, and the actual implementation is difficult (Zorpas et al., 2017). The premise of the implementation of subsidy measures is that local finance has a certain basic strength. Subsidy measures can positively strengthen waste recycling, management and other behaviors, but subsidy measures need to formulate reasonable subsidy standards, and they need to be subsidized continuously and fairly, otherwise they cannot meet the return expectation of participants, or they cannot get timely subsidies after a certain recycling, which will lead to people’s doubts about this system and lose the strengthening effect (Huang et al., 2013; Sun, 2020). The real right exchange is mainly realized by mortgage return. Part of the property (the property corresponding to the waste recycling value) is mortgaged as creditor’s rights, and then the mortgagor exchanges the waste real right to return the creditor’s rights. The advantage of mortgage return is to set a risk (if the waste cannot be recycled, the mortgaged property cannot be retrieved) to encourage the mortgagor to complete the recycling task on time and with quality, but the operation procedure is more complex.

Game theory, known as the “science of strategy” provides a useful tool to help scientists to understand how decision-makers (players) interact in an interdependent situation called the “game” (Eleftheriadou and Mylopoulos, 2008). In this theory, each player decides to optimize their own interests (returns), taking into account that the responses made by other players which may affect the actual results (Madani, 2010). Compared with quantitative simulation and optimal resource management model, the advantage of the game theory is to consider various details of the problem and estimate the possible solutions without quantitative information about benefits (Barati et al., 2021). The mixed strategy game theory is a theory that studies multi-person decision-making. It is not like the pure strategy game theory, and randomly selects a strategy with a certain probability distribution under the given information, which is closer to reality. In this game theory, Nash equilibrium is often used to analyze the outcome of the strategic interaction of several decision-makers (Limaei, 2010).

In this study, there was an interest conflict between farmers’ pesticide packaging waste recycling behavior and government incentive behavior. Therefore, it is feasible to analyze farmers’ and government’s strategies in the behavior of pesticide packaging waste recycling based on game theory. This article did not take the mixed policy scenario into account to clearly compare the utility differences of the three policies. Under the three separate policy scenarios, it constructed the game analysis framework of a mixed strategy between the government and farmers. The game analysis assumed that the government and farmers could fully understand each other’s strategic behavior and revenue function, that is, the information of both sides of the game was entirely open to each other.

2.2.1 Theoretical Mechanism of the Punish Policy

Punish policy required the government to impose a fine on farmers who, according to a certain standard, failed to recycle pesticide packaging waste. The punish policy’s motivation was to increase the cost or expense of farmers who discard pesticide packaging waste at will, reduce farmers’ revenue in disguise, and internalize negative externalities.

Punitive policies have positive external effects on the recycling of pesticide packaging waste. As shown in Figure 1, MPR and MSR represented the individual marginal income and social marginal income of pesticide packaging waste recycling, respectively, and MC represented the marginal cost. The horizontal axis represented the recycling amount of pesticide packaging waste. On the principle of maximizing personal income, farmers determined the recycling amount of waste as Q1 based on the principle of maximizing personal income. However, due to the existence of environmental benefits (i.e., the positive externality of recycling), the social marginal benefits were greater than the individual marginal benefits (MSR > MPR), and the equilibrium point of the recycling amount for maximizing social benefits is located in Q2, and Q1 is less than Q2. To reduce the penalty caused by not recycling packaging waste, farmers often increased the recycling amount. Thus, the curve below representing personal marginal income shifted from MPR to MPR′ and gradually move closer to MSR, and the equilibrium amount of pesticide packaging waste recycled by farmers will return to the socially optimal level Q2.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. Influence of the punish policy on the recycling level of pesticide packaging waste.

Under the fining strategy implemented by the government, it was assumed that the government supervision cost was C1 and the fine was F. If farmers do not recycle pesticide packaging waste, the reputation loss of being accused or complained was -R2, and the probability of being supervised and fined was λ1, farmers’ revenue and cost of recycling waste was S1 and C2, respectively, and the probability of being wrongly fined due to other accidental reasons was λ0. Under the government’s not fining strategy, waste was discarded at will, and villagers were dissatisfied and complained, thus the loss of government reputation was -R1. It was further assumed that the probability of government fining and not fining was q1 and 1-q1, respectively, if the recycling probability of farmers was p1 and the probability of not recycling was 1-p1. The game revenue matrix under complete information is given below:

When figuring out the Nash equilibrium of the mixed strategy, to maximize the utility, one party should have equal revenue regardless of the other party’s strategy, that is:

When the government chooses the pure strategy of “fining,” the expected utility of farmers is:

Uf1+=p1(C2+S1λ0F)+(1p1)(R2λ1F).(1)

When the government chooses the pure strategy of “not fining,” the expected utility of farmers is:

Uf1=p1(C2+S1)+(1p1)(R2).(2)

If Uf1+=Uf1, the expected utility of farmers was not affected by the change of the government strategy. At this time, the equilibrium of farmers’ recycling probability can be obtained as follows:

p1=λ1λ1λ0=1+λ0λ1λ0.(3)

The equilibrium of expected utility of farmers can be obtained by substitution of p1*:

Uf1=λ1F(−C2+S1)+λ0FR2λ1Fλ0F=λ1(−C2+S1)+λ0R2λ1λ0 .(4)

Similarly, if the government expects utility Ug1+=Ug1, it is not affected by the change of the farmers’ strategy, that is, the equilibrium of the government fining probability is:

q1(λ0FC1)+(1q1)0=q1(λ1FC1)+(1q1)(R1),
q1=R1(λ1λ0)F+R1.(5)

The equilibrium of expected utility of the government can be obtained by substitution of q1*:

Ug1=R1λ0FR1C1λ1F+R1λ0F.(6)

When the recycling probability of farmers was p1* and the probability of government fining was q1*, the game between farmers and the government ceases to achieve a strategic equilibrium. In the mixed strategy game, one party’s strategy choice was determined by the other party’s strategy choice probability and revenue function. If the probability of government fining q1 > q1*, the revenue functions of farmers’ recycling and not recycling are compared. If S1 + R2 + (λ1 - λ0) F > C2, λ0 can be regarded as infinitesimal, meaning, under the condition of farmers’ pesticide packaging waste, when the sum of the revenue, reputation growth, and opportunity cost of being fined, recycling was more significant than the cost. Here, farmers’ best choice was to recycle; otherwise, farmers should choose not to recycle. Therefore, when farmers do not recycle, the higher the probability of being punished by supervision (λ1), the amount of fine (F), the recycling revenue (S1), and the reputation growth (R2) were, the lower the risk of being wrongly fined (λ0) was when recycling, the smaller the value of (q1*) was, the greater the possibility of the actual fining probability of the government being q1 > q1*, and more farmers tended to choose to recycle.

However, in some cases, the high cost of supervision (C1) may result in the reduction of the government’s punish. The possibility (λ1) of being supervised and fined decreases when farmers do not recycle. Therefore, it is easy for farmers to have the fluke mind of “even if they discard the waste at will, they will not be found and punished.” As a result, the opportunistic behavior of discarding waste into other people’s fields will occur. Consequently, the intervention effect of the punish policy on recycling pesticide packaging waste is greatly weakened.

2.2.2 Theoretical Mechanism of the Subsidy and Reward Policy

It was assumed that the government subsidizes the farmers according to the quantity and specifications of pesticide packaging waste recycled by farmers. The essence of the subsidy was a “negative fine,” so the subsidy and reward policy and punish policy had the exact intervention mechanism, which was equivalent to the direct upward movement of MPR (the individual marginal income curve) in Figure 1. When the government was under the subsidy strategy, the subsidy standard was S2. As there are certain thresholds and requirements for subsidy distribution, the probability of farmers receiving subsidies after recycling was set at λ2, and the probability of farmers without recycling receiving subsidies by speculation (such as recycling other packaging materials) was λ22. The enthusiasm of farmers participating under the subsidy and reward policy measures was the opposite of the punish policy. Hence, its implementation cost (C3) was lower than the supervision cost of the punish policy. While other behavior strategies were consistent with those of the punish policy. Assuming that the government does not subsidize the farmers, the reputation loss caused by farmers’ failure to recycle packaging waste was R1, the cost of farmers’ recycling waste was C2, the income was S1, and the reputation loss of farmers who did not recycle the complaints was R2.

It was assumed that the probability of the government adopting subsidy policy was q2 and that of not adopting the subsidy policy was 1 − q2 and the probability of farmers recycling pesticide packaging waste was p2 and that of not recycling was 1 − p2. The game revenue matrix under complete information is constructed, as follows, in Tables 1, 2:

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Game revenue matrix between farmers and government under the intervention mechanism of punish.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. Game revenue matrix between farmers and government under the intervention mechanism of subsidy and reward.

Nash equilibrium of the farmers’ mixed strategy is:

p2(C2+S1+λ2S2)+(1p2)(R2+λ22S2)=p2(C2+S1)+(1p2)(R2)p2=λ22λ22λ2.(7)

The equilibrium of expected utility of farmers can be obtained by substitution of p2*:

Uf2=λ22(−C2+S1)+λ2R2λ22λ2.(8)

Nash equilibrium of the mixed strategy of the government is:

q2(C3λ2S2)+(1q2)0=q2(C3λ22S2)+(1q2)(R1),q2=R1R1+(λ2λ22)S2.(9)

The equilibrium of expected utility of the government can be obtained by substitution of q2*:

Ug2=R1C3R1λ2S2R1λ22S2+λ2S2.(10)

When the recycling probability of farmers was p2* or q2*, the game between farmers and the government ceases to achieve a strategic equilibrium. When the probability of government subsidy was q2 > q2*, the revenue functions of farmers who recycled and didn’t recycle were compared. If S1 + R2 + (λ2λ22) S2 > C2, and λ22 was regarded as close to infinitesimal, it meant that the sum of revenue, reputation growth, and subsidy obtained by farmers’ behavior of pesticide packaging waste recycling was more significant than the recycling cost, farmers’ optimal choice was recycling. As shown in Eq. 9, when the farmers recycle packaging waste, the higher the λ2 (the probability of obtaining the subsidy), S2 (the subsidy standard of subsidies), S1 (the income after recycling), and R2 (reputation growth obtained by recycling) will be. When the farmers did not recycle packaging waste, the smaller the λ22 (the probability of obtaining speculative subsidies) would be, and thus, the smaller the q2* would be. The greater the probability of actual government subsidies to be q2 > q2* was, the more the farmers tend to recycle.

In reality, due to the restriction of financial funds and the limited scope and intensity of subsidies, the government may reduce S2 (the subsidy standard) or λ2 (the probability of farmers receiving subsidies after recycling). When the expected amount of subsidies was not enough to compensate farmers for the labor cost, time cost, and transaction cost of recycling pesticide packaging waste, the influence of the subsidy and reward policy in stimulating farmers’ recycling enthusiasm would be slightly insufficient.

2.2.3 Theoretical Mechanism of the Mortgage Return Policy

According to the aforementioned analysis, it can be seen that the punish or subsidy and reward system may fail, and some regions tried to replace it with the mortgage return policy. Mortgage return required the behavioral subject to pay a certain fee (i.e., deposit) in advance for the potential damage. If the potential damage does not occur, the payment will be returned. Precisely, under the guidance of the local government, pesticide packaging waste recycling points were set up in each agricultural material distribution store, and the mortgage amount can offset part of the pesticide price. The farmers pay it together when purchasing pesticides. When the farmers buy pesticides next time and return the previous pesticide packaging waste to the store, this part of the mortgage will be refunded. The incentive mechanism of such policies lies in the fact that the mortgage can be returned only when the farmers complete the specified recycling of pesticide packaging waste. Based on the standard calculation of 0.1 yuan/piece of bagged pesticide with the specification of ≦10 g/10 ml or bottled pesticide with the specification of ≦100 ml, assuming that farmers plant rice and wheat for two seasons, generally, the pesticide should be used in wheat at least three times per season (including two times of herbicides: one time for soil sealing, the other for stem and leaf treatment, and fungicide for one single time). Pesticide should be used in rice at least five to six times per season (including two times of herbicides: one time for soil sealing, the other of stem and leaf treatment, as well as three to four times of fungicides and pesticides). On average, about 90 bottles (bags) of pesticides and additives (pesticide additives include dissolution-aided, sedimentation-aided, penetration-aided, and other types) are used per hectare each time. Hence, farmers need to pay a mortgage of about 72–81 yuan/hm2 every year, which means that if the packaging waste is not recycled, it can be regarded as a loss of 72–81 yuan/hm2 of crops. If recycled, farmers need to pay extra labor costs for centralized placement and the carriage of packaging wastes after use, since the farmers return the last packaging waste at the same time when purchasing pesticides next time, there is no additional transportation cost. In addition, due to the wide-existed monopoly or oligopoly in the distribution market of agricultural materials in the villages, towns, and counties in China, the local government only needs to negotiate with a few monopoly dealers to implement the mortgage return policy. The local farmers can only buy pesticides at a price including a mortgage, which provides necessary conditions for the smooth implementation of the policy. Therefore, to control the possible impact of “market monopoly,” including complete monopoly and oligopoly, on policy intervention effect, all sample areas selected in the empirical test below were supply markets monopolized by agricultural products.

As shown in Figure 2, the horizontal axis represented the discarded and recovered amount of pesticide packaging waste from left to right. MPC was the marginal private cost, meaning the cost of discarding (or recycling) waste. MSC was social marginal cost equal to marginal private cost plus environmental damage cost. When there was no mortgage, Q2 (the equilibrium point) of personal waste disposal was greater than Q1, meaning Q2 (the recycled amount) was less than Q1. To compensate for negative externalities, paying a mortgage was equivalent to the marginal private cost moving from MPC to MPC′. When the mortgage can compensate for the gap between marginal private and social marginal costs, the equilibrium point of discarded amount (recycled amount) moves from Q2 to Q1. Mortgage return gave farmers an obvious incentive to adopt recycling behavior because it can enable them to withdraw environmental costs again. Once the waste was discarded at will, the environmental cost must be paid in advance.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. Influence of the mortgage return policy on the recycling level of pesticide packaging waste.

It was assumed that the probability of farmers recovering pesticide packaging waste to obtain the return of the mortgage was λ3, the deposit standard was S3, and the government implementation cost was C4. The probability of receiving the return of the mortgage by speculation when not recycling the packaging waste was λ33, with other conditions utterly consistent with the first two policies. Supposing that the probability of the government adopting the mortgage return policy was q3, the probability of not adopting was q3, farmers’ recycling was p3, and not recycling was 1-p3. The game revenue matrix under complete information is shown in Table 3.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 3. Game revenue matrix between farmers and government under the intervention mechanism of mortgage return.

As mentioned previously, Nash equilibrium of the farmers’ mixed strategy is:

p3(C2S3+λ3S3+S1)+(1p3)(R2S3+λ33S3)=p3(C2+S1)+(1p3)(R2),p3=λ33λ33λ3.(11)

The equilibrium of expected utility of farmers can be obtained by substitution of p3*:

Uf3=(λ331)(C2S1)+R2(1λ3)λ3λ33.(12)

Nash equilibrium of the mixed strategy of the government is:

q3(C4+S3λ3S3)+(1q3)0=q3(C4+S3λ33S3)+(1q3)(R1),q3=R1R1+S3(λ3λ33).(13)

The equilibrium of expected utility of the government can be obtained by substitution of q3*:

Ug3=R1C4+R1S3R1λ3S3R1λ33S3+λ3S3.(14)

p3* and q3* were the probability Nash equilibrium points for the government to implement the mortgage return policy and farmers to recycle pesticide packaging waste. When it was on the Nash equilibrium solution, the government and farmers stop the game and realize the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium solution. When q3 > q3*, the revenue functions of farmers recycling or not recycling are compared, and λ33 was regarded as close to infinitesimal, which meant that when the sum of the income, reputation growth, and mortgage amount obtained by farmers from recycling pesticide packaging waste was greater than the farmers’ recycling cost, the farmers’ best choice was recycling, otherwise not recycling. Therefore, the higher the S3 (the mortgage amount), λ3 (the probability that farmers got the mortgage return after recycling), S1 (the income), and R2 (reputation growth) after recycling were, the lower the λ33 (the probability of obtaining speculative deposit return when not recycling) and the value of q3* were, and thus, the greater the probability of the government adopting the mortgage return strategy to be q3 > q3*, the more the farmers preferred to choose to recycle.

Compared with punish, subsidy, and reward policies, the mortgage return policy requires very low government supervision cost and public financial investment. Once effectively implemented, the reward mechanism can operate automatically. Therefore, for the cost of government supervision, C4 < C1, and C4 < C3, it can be inferred that the relationship among λ1 (the probability of being fined for farmers who did not recycle), λ2 (the probability of receiving subsidies after recycling), and λ3 (the probability of receiving mortgage return after recycling) was as follows: λ2 > λ1 and λ3 > λ1. Therefore, from Eqs 5, 9, and 13, it can be found that q3* < q1* and q3* < q2*.

According to the aforementioned mixed strategy equilibrium analysis, we assumed that the government chooses to implement three policies, respectively, and satisfies the conditions that S1 + R2 + (λ1λ0) F > C2, S1 + R2 + (λ2λ22) S2 > C2, and S1 + R2 + (λ3λ33) S3 > C2. Then, when the probability of the government implementing the policy was greater than q* (the equilibrium solution), farmers will choose to recycle. It can be seen from Figure 3 that the value ranged satisfying q3 > q3* was the largest. In other words, under the mortgage return policy, farmers were most likely to choose to adopt the recycling strategy.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. Interval relationship of implementation probability of three policies which was greater than the equilibrium solution.

Based on the aforementioned analysis, the following hypotheses can be drawn:

H1: When the sum of the income, reputation, and fine/subsidy/mortgage amount of farmers who recycle pesticide packaging waste was greater than their recycling cost, the three policies can improve the probability of farmers’ recycling of pesticide packaging waste.

H2: The intervention effect of the mortgage return policy on farmers’ recycling of pesticide packaging waste was greater than that of the punish policy and subsidy and reward policy.

3 Methodology

3.1 PSM Model

The best way to evaluate whether a policy impacts farmers’ recycling behavior is to compare the changes in farmers’ recycling behavior with and without the intervention of the policy. However, the ideal random test data cannot be obtained, so it is necessary to construct a counterfactual causal state. Thus, the propensity score matching (PSM) was used to analyze whether the three policies of punish, reward, and mortgage can encourage farmers to recycle pesticide packaging waste (D'Agostino, 1998).

Therefore, we use the logit model to estimate farmers’ probability under the three types of policy intervention. The model is as follows:

Pjn(Xm)=prob((jn=1|Xm)=exp(βXm)1+exp(βXm)(n=1,2,3),(15)

where Pjn(Xm) represented the probability of farmers being intervened by the n-type of the policy and j was the treatment variable. It should be made clear that the meaning of “farmers subject to policy intervention” meant that farmers were within the policy’s coverage and had a perception and understanding of it. In other words, farmers who felt indifferent to the policy would not change their behavior whether they were in the policy pilot area or not. Therefore, it was inaccurate only to take “whether farmers were within the scope of policy implementation” as the treatment and identification variable of intervention effect, which echoed and corresponded with the hypothesis of “complete information of both sides of the game” in the aforementioned theoretical mechanism analysis. If the corresponding policies were implemented in the region and farmers perceive them, the value jn was 1; otherwise, it was 0, and Xm was a covariate (matching variable). After obtaining the propensity score, the average intervention effect of three types of policies on whether farmers scientifically recycle pesticide packaging waste was obtained through appropriate matching methods:

ATTn=E{E[Y1i|j=1,Pjn(Xm)]E[Y0i|j=0,Pjn(Xm)]}(n=1,2,3),(16)

where Y1i and Y0i represented the behavior results of the same farmer in the treatment group and the control group, respectively.

3.2 Variable Selection

This article selected the ability of farmers to scientifically recycle pesticide packaging waste as the dependent variable. Considering that the way farmers deal with pesticide packaging waste, in reality, was not fixed, this article took the question “the treatment behavior of pesticide packaging after the last spraying” as the measurement standard, including 1) placing pesticide packaging in special recycling equipment or places, 2) taking pesticide packaging home, 3) tossing pesticide packaging to the roadside dump/garbage can/dustbin, and 4) throwing pesticide packaging to the field or ridge. Suppose the farmer chooses 1), and places it in the pesticide packaging waste recycling bin (bins). In that case, it was judged that the farmer had implemented the scientific recycling behavior. It was assumed that the farmer has not implemented the scientific recycling behavior in other cases.

Since some farmers are insensitive to the outside information, being informed of the policy does not mean that all farmers can recognize the existence and content of the policy and make conscious or behavioral responses. Therefore, “whether farmers are informed of the punish policy and have a perception of the policy,” “whether farmers are informed of the subsidy and reward policy and have a perception of the policy,” and “whether farmers are informed of the mortgage return policy and have a perception of the policy” were taken as three treatment variables: j1, j2, and j3.

According to the treatment variables, the selection of covariates needed to take two factors into account: first, the farmers’ knowledge of the policy, that is, the administrative area where the farmers were located, according to the actual investigation, generally promotes the pilot policy in towns; the second was whether farmers perceive and understand the policy, which was related to the individual characteristics of farmers, including the age, gender, education level, planting area, the proportion of agricultural income in household agricultural income, and the cognition of hazard caused by pesticide packaging waste. In addition, due to only four female respondents in the sample whose proportion was too small, the gender factor was not considered temporarily.

3.3 Data Source

The data used in this study were obtained from the survey of farmers in major grain-producing counties (cities and districts) in northern, central, and southern Jiangsu Province from August to September 2019. The questionnaire included the essential characteristics of farmers, such as production characteristics, recycling behavior of pesticide packaging waste, and cognition of agricultural non-point source pollution. According to the geographical distribution of the administrative regions of Jiangsu Province and the pilot situation of pesticide packaging waste recycling, four cities (Jingjiang City, Jintan District of Changzhou City, Jiangning District of Nanjing City, and Suining Country of Xuzhou City) were selected as the research areas, and the pilot and non-pilot towns with similar production conditions were chosen from each county (city, district) (Figure 4). The distribution of specific sample points is shown in Table 4. According to the actual scale distribution, 20–40 farmers were selected from each town. A total of 585 effective samples were taken, of which 65 were provided with pesticides by the flight prevention organization. After the operation, the packaging waste was taken away without the need for farmers to recycle. The remaining farmers were self-defended and autonomous, or organizations did not provide medicine, and these farmers needed to purchase and recycle pesticides by themselves. To control the influence of the degree of competition in the sales market of agricultural materials on the policy effect, this study selected the areas where the agricultural materials sale in villages and towns were of monopoly or oligopoly, and the final sample consisted of 452 households.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. Map of four pilot cities selected in this study.

TABLE 4
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 4. Distribution of samples.

3.4 Descriptive Statistics of the Sample

3.4.1 Sample Area and Policy Description

The recycling of pesticide packaging waste was in the early stage at present, and only some pilot counties and towns had implemented relevant policies. In the sample, the areas implementing the punish policy were mainly distributed in Lukou Town (Jiangning), Gaozuo Town (Suining), and Suihe Town (Suining). A total of 92 households have been investigated. In Suihe Town (Suining), farmers were fined according to the polluted area. Once the pesticide packaging waste was found and discarded in the field, the land managers would be fined 450 yuan/hm2, and the others would be fined according to the number of packaging waste items, ranging from 0.1 to 0.5 yuan per bottle. The regions implementing the subsidy and reward policy were distributed in Xieqiao Town (Jingjiang), Shengci Town (Jingjiang), Xilai Town (Jingjiang), Zhulin Town (Jintan), and Hengxi Town (Jiangning), where there were 101 effective samples. The waste recycling policy was promoted with the zero difference distribution of pesticides. Waste pesticide bottles and pesticide bags from the zero difference distribution were subsidized by 0.3 yuan and 0.1 yuan, respectively. The mortgage return policy was implemented in Qing’an Town (Suining), with 32 valid samples. The government had set up recycling equipment at fixed agricultural materials sales points, with the agricultural materials dealers collecting the mortgage. The charging standard for bags with ≦10 g/10 ml or bottles with a specification of ≤100 ml was 0.1 yuan/bottle (bag), which gradually increases according to the mortgage standard of different packaging specification levels. The mortgage will be returned to farmers after waste recycling. The local governments of villages and towns where the remaining 227 households live only conducted criticism and education or did not implement any recycling policy.

3.4.2 Description of Farmers’ Characteristics

According to the treatment variable setting mentioned previously, among the three groups of policy intervention, the farmers in the “mortgage return” group had the highest perception of the policy, over 90%. This was followed by the “subsidy and reward” group, with farmers’ perception reaching 66.49%. The “punish” group was the lowest, with only 45.70% of the farmers who were aware of the local implementation of the punish policy. Compared with areas without policies, the four groups of farmers had no significant differences in education level, number of the family agricultural labor force, participation in production organizations, and other characteristics (Table 5). Due to the high level of non-agricultural employment in Lukou Town, Jiangning, the proportion of farmers’ agricultural income and land management scale in the punish group was significantly lower than those in other countries’ groups. Generally, for pesticides with a large standard dosage used per hectare, manufacturers often produce large barrels of 1, 2, 5, and 10 L, and other specifications for large-scale households or farms. Theoretically, the higher the scale level is, the higher the proportion of large-scale packaged pesticides is and the lower the difficulty of recycling is. However, in reality, considering the matches between the pesticide dosage per hectare, the dispensing dilution ratio, and the capacity of various common dispensing barrels. A variety of small packaging pesticides designed by the manufacturer enable farmers to pour a package (bottle) of pesticides to exactly match a barrel of water for dilution, without the need to use measuring cups (barrels) for dispensing, which was convenient and time-saving. Therefore, in addition to small-scale peasants, medium-sized farmers with self-defense and autonomy tended to choose small packaging pesticides. According to the survey, farmers with a business scale of more than 5.33 hm2 and adopting efficient plant protection machinery socialization services have a significantly higher probability of using large packaging pesticides than other farmers. As shown in Table 5, although the average household size of each group reaches about 13.33 hm2, only about half of the farmers had a demand of large packaging pesticides.

TABLE 5
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 5. Basic characteristics of farmers in different policy application areas.

3.4.3 Farmers’ Cognitive Results After Policy Intervention

From the perspective of farmers’ cognition and recycling behavior of pesticide packaging waste, the performance of the subsidy and reward group and mortgage return group was significantly better than the other two groups (Table 6). The proportion of farmers in all three groups of punish, subsidy and reward, and mortgage return, who had known or known well about the relevant management regulations in the Soil Pollution Prevention and Control Law of the People’s Republic of China, has reached more than 78%. Of which, 25.74% of farmers in the subsidy and reward group had known the subject of recycling responsibility, while 21.1% of farmers in the non-policy intervention group did not know at all. Similarly, the subsidy and reward group and mortgage return group also had a higher awareness of the harm caused by pesticide packaging waste to the environment, and there were 78.22–84.38% of farmers who believed that the residual pesticides of pesticide packaging waste were serious to the environment, respectively. According to the regulations, the proportion of farmers in the mortgage return group was the highest, and 68.75% of farmers recycled pesticide packaging waste to special equipment or places. The proportion of the subsidy and reward group and punish group was 44.55–18.48%, respectively, while only 8.41% of farmers in areas without policy implementation participate in recycling.

TABLE 6
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 6. Farmers’ awareness and recycling behavior of pesticide packaging waste in areas with different policy application areas.

4 Results and Discussion

4.1 Matching Balance Test

According to the setting of treatment variables, the samples were divided into the punish treatment group–punish control group, reward treatment group–reward control group, and mortgage treatment group–mortgage control group for propensity score matching, respectively. Due to the limited sample size, the matching method of one-to-one effectively returning to the nearest neighborhood was used for sample matching. The smaller the standardized deviation after matching is, the better the matching effect is. Generally, whether the absolute value of standardized deviation is less than 20% will be checked. In the balance test results, the absolute value of standardized deviation after variable matching was less than 20%, and the matching effect was relatively good. The matching results are shown in Table 7.

TABLE 7
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 7. Matching balance test.

4.2 Intervention Effects of Different Policies on Farmers’ Behavior of Pesticide Packaging Waste Recycling

As shown in Table 8, the average intervention effects of the three policies were measured by the one-to-one nearest-neighbor matching method. The results showed that the three kinds of policies all had a significant positive impact on the recycling behavior of pesticide packaging waste of farmers who had a perception of policies, which supported Hypothesis 1. This result indicated that farmers gradually realize the harm of pesticide packaging waste, not only the harm of pesticide residues, but also the long-term consequences caused by improper treatment of packaging waste, so they took a positive attitude toward the recycling of pesticide packaging waste. In terms of the degree of impact, the punish policy had a significant impact only at the level of 10%, where the intervention effect was the weakest, the subsidy and reward policy had a considerable impact on the level of 5%. Under the intervention of a single subsidy and reward policy, the probability of farmers recycling pesticide packaging waste increased by 32.7% compared with the one without intervention. The mortgage return policy significantly impacted on the 1% level, where the intervention effect was the best. Under a single policy, the recovery probability of farmers can be increased by 44.8%. Based on these results, Hypothesis 2 was supported.

TABLE 8
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 8. Average intervention effect of three policies calculated based on the one-to-one nearest-neighbor matching method.

4.3 Discussion

In terms of empirical researches, many scholars have established various models supplemented by a variety of methods to evaluate the effect of pro-environmental policies, such as Heckman selection model and Poisson model (Song et al., 2020), Driving Force-Pressure-State-Impact-Response model with the entropy method (Qu and Liu, 2017), and Structural equation modeling with the theory of planned behavior (Sarma, 2022). In fact, to accurately evaluate the effect of a policy, the most accurate method is to select a period of time before (t0) and after (t1) the occurrence of the policy, and observe the changes of the experimental group and the control group at the same time. However, due to many studies that were often conducted after policies have been occurred, the data of t0 period were not obtained, and in reality, it is impossible to select two groups of almost homogeneous samples for the coverage and non-coverage of the policy. Therefore, the PSM method is usually used to manually construct a more reasonable treatment group and control group to improve the accuracy of estimation (Wen et al., 2022). In this study, PSM was used to analyze whether the three policies of punishment, reward, and mortgage can promote farmers to recycle pesticide packaging waste, which is reasonable.

From the perspective of public economics, pesticide packaging waste recycling is a typical public activity with positive externalities, and its governance process needs the extensive participation of farmers (Bouma et al., 2008; Lu et al., 2022). However, farmers need extra time and energy to participate in the recycling of pesticide packaging waste, and the benefits brought by recycling, such as beautifying the environment, and reducing pollution, are not exclusive. Therefore, it is necessary to formulate relevant regulatory and compensation policies to transform externality into internality (Xie et al., 2017). In addition, it is difficult for the government to supervise, which is easy to produce “free riding.” Therefore, relevant government departments need to issue reward and punishment policies to forcibly restrict farmers’ behavior from the outside (Al Zadjali et al., 2013; Brodhagen et al., 2017; Pan et al., 2021), which was consistent with the view of this study. Moreover, Zhao and Zhou, (2021) found that social trust can promote the implementation efficiency of reward and punishment policies.

In this study, the effect of mortgage return policy was better than subsidy and reward. Some researchers indicated that economic compensation had significant positive influence on farmers’ pro-environmental behavior (Wang B. et al., 2019; Li et al., 2021; Was et al., 2021). However, since the promotion of the economic subsidy and reward policy on recycling of pesticide packaging waste by farmers’ is regulated by many factors, such as recycling price, awareness of pesticide residue risk, social norms, and social trust, multiple factors are needed to work together to optimize the effect of economic subsidies (Trujillo-Barrera et al., 2016; Sharafi et al., 2018; Xu et al., 2021). While the mortgage return policy required farmers to pay environmental costs in advance, in order to obtain the maximum individual marginal cost, farmers always have strong endogenous driving force, thus leading to the fact that the probability of pesticide packaging waste recycling was the highest. The mortgage return policy is often adopted in the waste recycling and recycling industry, such as the recycling of plastic bottles and batteries. By implementing the mortgage return system, the holders of contaminated products can be stimulated to reclaim the mortgage without randomly discarding the potentially polluted waste products into the environmental medium, so as to effectively promote the safe placement and recycling of products (Linderhof et al., 2019; Roca et al., 2022). Thus, this practice of bringing the environmental pollution caused by farmers’ behavior into the environmental protection cost in advance also provides a new idea for the formulation and implementation of pro-environmental behavior policies.

Although the intervention effects of different policies regarding pesticide packaging waste recycling in this study were determined, there are still some limitations, which are worthy of further discussion. First, the heterogeneity of farmers, including income difference, education level, environmental awareness, and a series of factors, may lead to their different environmental awareness and then affect their behavioral response to the recycling policy. Second, because the policy implementation is still in the pilot stage, there are few sample areas for this study, which may influence the accuracy of the effect of policy intervention. Therefore, the follow-up research needs to explore further the differences of policies on the intervention mechanisms of distinct subjects and scientifically investigate the differences of policy effects caused by farmers’ heterogeneity, to improve the accuracy of policy formulation and implementation.

5 Main Conclusion and Policy Implication

5.1 Main Conclusion

In this study, 452 farmers in Jiangsu Province were taken as the research sample, and based on the game theory and PSM model, this article empirically analyzed and compared the intervention effects of different policies on farmers’ behavior of pesticide packaging waste recycling. The results showed that: 1) the three kinds of approaches of punish, subsidy and reward, and mortgage return all could significantly influence pesticide packaging waste recycling by farmers in the pilot area; 2) different intervention policies had obvious differences on the recycling behavior of pesticide packaging waste of farmers, and among them, the effect of mortgage return policy was the most prominent, with the probability of farmers recycling pesticide packaging waste being 44.8% higher than those without intervention; 3) the intervention of the mortgage return policy was equivalent to charging farmers “the fine under the condition of non-recycling” in advance. The “fine” can only be returned when farmers’ recycling behavior occurs, effectively stimulating the enthusiasm for active recycling to reduce interest losses. Thus, it was an incentive system with low government supervision costs and financial pressure and can operate automatically, while the intervention effects of the punish policy and subsidy and reward policy were relatively weak due to high implementation cost, lack of a critical law enforcement system, excessive local financial pressure, and other reasons.

5.2 Policy Implication

Based on the aforementioned analysis and conclusion, putting the uneven quality of farmers into consideration, this study indicated that in areas with more pesticide packaging wastes, the first trial experience of Jiangsu Province can be used for reference. This included establishing supporting policies for implementing the Soil Pollution Prevention and Control Law of the People’s Republic of China, implementing active intervention, and improving the effectiveness of the rule of law. Therefore, the following suggestions were put forward:

First, improve the administrative supporting rules and regulations related to the recycling of pesticide packaging waste, bring the recycling of pesticide packaging waste into the administrative law enforcement system, and strengthen the guidance and restraint of informal systems such as social norms.

Second, the government can increase financial support, improve the standard of recycling subsidies, strengthen first-line level management and the allocation of human and material resources in areas with strong local financial strength, implement recycling, and improve the effectiveness of law implementation.

Third, the mortgage return recovery system should be actively promoted in areas with a high monopoly in the pesticide distribution market, which can not only improve the recovery efficiency but also reduce the government supervision cost and financial pressure.

Fourth, strengthen the publicity and popularization of government policies and comprehensively improve farmers’ attention, perception, and understanding of relevant recycling policy mechanisms, thus continuously and effectively promoting farmers’ recycling of pesticide packaging waste.

Finally, we can implement the real name system of pesticide procurement, establish a pesticide packaging waste recovery and treatment and traceability system coordinated by producers, operators, and users, and comprehensively promote the recovery and treatment of pesticide packaging waste.

Data Availability Statement

The raw data supporting the conclusion of this article will be made available by the authors, without undue reservation.

Author Contributions

NH: data curation, initial version writing, and writing—review and editing; QZ: investigation, methodology, and data analysis; CL: investigation and formal analysis; HS: conceptualization and supervision.

Funding

This research was funded by the Science Foundation of Ministry of Education of China (Grant Number: 20YJCZH044), Jiangsu Agriculture Science and Technology Innovation Fund (Grant Number: CX(21)1010), and Jiangsu Middle and Late Maturing Garlic Industry Cluster Construction Project (Grant Number: 0040222022101).

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

The reviewer DS declared a shared affiliation with the author CL to the handling editor at the time of review.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors, and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Abadie, L. M., Galarraga, I., Milford, A. B., and Gustavsen, G. W. (2016). Using Food Taxes and Subsidies to Achieve Emission Reduction Targets in Norway. J. Clean. Prod. 134, 280–297. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.09.054

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Al Zadjali, S., Morse, S., Chenoweth, J., and Deadman, M. (2013). Disposal of Pesticide Waste from Agricultural Production in the Al-Batinah Region of Northern Oman. Sci. Total Environ. 463-464, 237–242. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2013.06.014

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Badrane, N., AitDaoud, N., Ghandi, M., Zalagh, F., El Bouazzi, O., Soulaymani, A., et al. (2018). Quel rôle du laboratoire d'analyses toxicologiques dans l'évaluation du risque des produits de contrebande ? Toxicol. Anal. Clinique 30 (2), S79. doi:10.1016/j.toxac.2018.04.112

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bagheri, A., Emami, N., Allahyari, M. S., and Damalas, C. A. (2018). Pesticide Handling Practices, Health Risks, and Determinants of Safety Behavior Among Iranian Apple Farmers. Hum. Ecol. Risk Assess. 24 (8), 2209–2223. doi:10.1080/10807039.2018.1443265

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Barati, A. A., Azadi, H., and Scheffran, J. (2021). Agricultural Land Fragmentation in Iran: Application of Game Theory. Land Use Policy 100, 105049. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2020.105049

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ben Khadda, Z., Fagroud, M., El Karmoudi, Y., Ezrari, S., Berni, I., De Broe, M., et al. (2021). Farmers' Knowledge, Attitudes, and Perceptions Regarding Carcinogenic Pesticides in Fez Meknes Region (Morocco). Ijerph 18, 10879. doi:10.3390/ijerph182010879

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bondori, A., Bagheri, A., Allahyari, M. S., and Damalas, C. A. (2019). Pesticide Waste Disposal Among Farmers of Moghan Region of Iran: Current Trends and Determinants of Behavior. Environ. Monit. Assess. 191 (30), 1–9. doi:10.1007/s10661-018-7150-0

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Botetzagias, I., Dima, A.-F., and Malesios, C. (2015). Extending the Theory of Planned Behavior in the Context of Recycling: The Role of Moral Norms and of Demographic Predictors. Resour. Conservation Recycl. 95, 58–67. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2014.12.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bouma, J., Bulte, E., and van Soest, D. (2008). Trust and Cooperation: Social Capital and Community Resource Management. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 56 (2), 155–166. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2008.03.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Briassoulis, D., Hiskakis, M., Karasali, H., and Briassoulis, C. (2014). Design of a European Agrochemical Plastic Packaging Waste Management Scheme-Pilot Implementation in Greece. Resour. Conservation Recycl. 87, 72–88. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2014.03.013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Brodhagen, M., Goldberger, J. R., Hayes, D. G., Inglis, D. A., Marsh, T. L., and Miles, C. (2017). Policy Considerations for Limiting Unintended Residual Plastic in Agricultural Soils. Environ. Sci. Policy 69, 81–84. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2016.12.014

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cao, H., Zhu, X. Q., Heijman, W., and Zhao, K. (2020). The Impact of Land Transfer and Farmers' Knowledge of Farmland Protection Policy on Pro-Environmental Agricultural Practices: The Case of Straw Return to Fields in Ningxia, China. J. Clean. Prod. 277, 123701. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.123701

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chen, Q., Yu, H. J., and Wang, Y. Z. (2021). Research on Modern Marine Environmental Governance in China: Subject Identification, Structural Characteristics, and Operational Mechanisms. Int. J. Environ. Res. Publ. Health 18 (9), 4485. doi:10.3390/ijerph18094485

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

D'Agostino, R. B. (1998). Propensity Score Methods for Bias Reduction in the Comparison of a Treatment to a Non-Randomized Control Group. Stat. Med. 17, 2265–2281. doi:10.1002/(sici)1097-0258(19981015)17:19<2265::aid-sim918>3.0.co;2-b

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dai, J., and Dong, H. (2014). Intensive Cotton Farming Technologies in China: Achievements, Challenges and Countermeasures. Field Crop Res. 155, 99–110. doi:10.1016/j.fcr.2013.09.017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Damalas, C. A., Telidis, G. K., and Thanos, S. D. (2008). Assessing Farmers' Practices on Disposal of Pesticide Waste After Use. Sci. Total Environ. 390, 341–345. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2007.10.028

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Eleftheriadou, E., and Mylopoulos, Y. (2008). Game Theoretical Approach to Conflict Resolution in Transboundary Water Resources Management. J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage. 134134, 4665–5473. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733-949610.1061/(asce)0733-9496(2008)134:5(466)

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ellis, H. S., and Fellner, W. (1943). External Economies and Diseconomies. Am. Econ. Rev. 33 (09), 493–511. doi:10.1086/256103

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Eras, J., Costa, J., Vilaró, F., Pelacho, A. M., Canela-Garayoa, R., and Martin-Closas, L. (2017). Prevalence of Pesticides in Postconsumer Agrochemical Polymeric Packaging. Sci. Total Environ. 580, 1530–1538. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2016.12.139

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

FAO/WHO (2008). International Code of Conduct on the Distribution and Use of Pesticides, Guidelines on Management Options for Empty Pesticide Containers (Rome). https://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/agphome/documents/Pests_Pesticides/Code/Containers08.pdf. htm (Accessed May 7, 2022).

Google Scholar

Fernandes, C. L. F., Volcão, L. M., Ramires, P. F., Moura, R. R. D., and Da Silva Júnior, F. M. R. (2020). Distribution of Pesticides in Agricultural and Urban Soils of Brazil: A Critical Review. Environ. Sci. Process. Impacts 22, 256–270. doi:10.1039/C9EM00433E

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Garbounis, G., and Komilis, D. (2021). A Modeling Methodology to Predict the Generation of Wasted Plastic Pesticide Containers: An Application to Greece. Waste Manag. 131, 177–186. doi:10.1016/j.wasman.2021.06.005

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hage, O., Söderholm, P., and Berglund, C. (2009). Norms and Economic Motivation in Household Recycling: Empirical Evidence from Sweden. Resour. Conservation Recycl. 53 (3), 155–165. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2008.11.003

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Huang, J., Wang, X., and Rozelle, S. (2013). The Subsidization of Farming Households in China's Agriculture. Food Policy 41 (8), 124–132. doi:10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.04.011

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jin, S., Bluemling, B., and Mol, A. P. J. (2018). Mitigating Land Pollution Through Pesticide Packages - The Case of a Collection Scheme in Rural China. Sci. Total Environ. 622-623, 502–509. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2017.11.330

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jones, K. A. (2014). The Recycling of Empty Pesticide Containers: An Industry Example of Responsible Waste Management. Outlook Pest Man. 25, 183–186. doi:10.1564/v25_apr_08

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, C. L., Zhang, Q., and Zhou, H. (2021). Social Norms, Economic Incentives and Farmers’ Recycling Behavior of Pesticide Packaging Waste. J. Nanjing Agric. Univ. 21 (1), 133. doi:10.19714/j.cnki.1671-7465.2021.0013

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, F. N., Zhang, J. B., and He, K. (2019). Impact of Informal Institutions and Environmental Regulations on Farmers’ Green Production Behavior: Based on Survey Data of 1105 Households in Hubei Province. Res. Sci. 41 (7), 1227. doi:10.18402/resci.2019.07.04

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, M. Y., Wang, J. J., Chen, K., and Wu, L. B. (2020). Willingness and Behaviors of Farmers' Green Disposal of Pesticide Packaging Waste in Henan, China: A Perceived Value Formation Mechanism Perspective. Ijerph 17 (11), 3753. doi:10.3390/ijerph17113753

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, Z., and Huang, J. (2018). How to Effectively Improve Pesticide Waste Governance: A Perspective of Reverse Logistics. Sustainability 10, 3622. doi:10.3390/su10103622

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, Z. Y., Luo, X. F., Huang, Y. Z., and Tang, L. (2020). Does Social Capital Stimulate or Constrain the Willingness of Farmers to Participate in Ecological Governance in Rural Areas. J. China Agric. Univ. 25 (2), 184. doi:10.11841/j.issn.1007-4333.2020.02.19

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Limaei, S. M. (2010). Mixed Strategy Game Theory, Application in Forest Industry. For. Policy Econ. 12, 527–531. doi:10.1016/j.forpol.2010.06.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Linderhof, V., Oosterhuis, F. H., Van Beukering, P. J. H., and Bartelings, H. (2019). Effectiveness of Deposit-Refund Systems for Household Waste in the Netherlands: Applying a Partial Equilibrium Model. J. Environ. Manag. 232, 842–850. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2018.11.102

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, J. Y., Ni, Q., Yao, L. Y., Lu, W. N., and Zhao, M. J. (2021). The Standard Measurement of Differential Compensation for Pesticide Packaging Waste Recycling: an Empirical Analysis Based on 1060 Fruit and Vegetable Farmers in Shaanxi Province. Chin. Rural. Econ. 6, 94.

Google Scholar

Lu, X. X. (1996). The New Institutional Economics [M]. Beijing: China Dev. Press.

Google Scholar

Lu, Y., Tan, Y., and Wang, H. (2022). Impact of Environmental Regulation on Green Technology Adoption by Farmers Microscopic Investigation Evidence from Pig Breeding in China. Front. Environ. Sci. 10, 885933. doi:10.3389/fenvs.2022.885933

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ma, Y., Chen, L., Zhao, X., Zheng, H., and Lü, Y. (2009). What Motivates Farmers to Participate in Sustainable Agriculture? Evidence and Policy Implications. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 16, 374–380. doi:10.1080/13504500903319047

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Madani, K. (2010). Game Theory and Water Resources. J. Hydrology 381, 225–238. doi:10.1016/j.jhydrol.2009.11.045

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Maldani, M., Dekaki, E., Nassiri, L., Ibijbijen, J., Dekaki, M., and State, J. (2017). State of Art on the Use of Pesticides in Meknes Region, Morocco. Am. J. Agric. Sci. 4 (6), 138–148.

Google Scholar

Marnasidis, S., Stamatelatou, K., Verikouki, E., and Kazantzis, K. (2018). Assessment of the Generation of Empty Pesticide Containers in Agricultural Areas. J. Environ. Manag. 224, 37–48. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2018.07.012

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Meng, F., Chen, H., Yu, Z. N., Xiao, W., and Tan, Y. Z. (2022). What Drives Farmers to Participate in Rural Environmental Governance? Evidence from Villages in Sandu Town, Eastern China. Sustainability 14, 3394. doi:10.3390/su14063394

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

National Bureau of Statistics of China (2021). China Rural Statistical Yearbook 2020. Beijing: China Statistics Press.

Google Scholar

Pan, Y., Ren, Y., and Luning, P. A. (2021). Factors Influencing Chinese Farmers' Proper Pesticide Application in Agricultural Products - A Review. Food Control., 122, 107788. doi:10.1016/j.foodcont.2020.107788

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Park, J., Díaz-Posada, N., and Mejía-Dugand, S. (2018). Challenges in Implementing the Extended Producer Responsibility in an Emerging Economy: The End-Of-Life Tire Management in Colombia. J. Clean. Prod. 189, 754–762. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.04.058

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pasdar, Y., Pirsaheb, M., Akramipour, R., Ahmadi-Jouibari, T., Fattahi, N., Sharafi, K., et al. (2017). Assessment of Triazine Herbicides Residual in Fruit and Vegetables Using Ultrasound Assisted Extraction-Dispersive Liquid-Liquid Microextraction with Solidification of Floating Organic Drop. J. Braz. Chem. Soc. 28, 1247–1255. doi:10.21577/0103-5053.20160287

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Pigou, A. C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare [M]. London: Macmillan.

Google Scholar

Pirsaheb, M., Fattahi, N., Rahimi, R., Sharafi, K., and Ghaffari, H. R. (2017). Evaluation of Abamectin, Diazinon and Chlorpyrifos Pesticide Residues in Apple Product of Mahabad Region Gardens: Iran in 2014. Food Chem. 231, 148–155. doi:10.1016/j.foodchem.2017.03.120

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Qu, Y., and Liu, Y. (2017). Evaluating the Low-Carbon Development of Urban China. Environ. Dev. Sustain 19, 939–953. doi:10.1007/s10668-016-9777-8

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Roca, M., Ayuso, S., Bala, A., Colomé, R., and Fullana-i-Palmer, P. (2022). Evaluating the Implementation of a Packaging Deposit and Refund System in Catalonia. Two Surveys on Citizenship's Expected Behaviour. Sci. Total Environ. 806, 150640. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2021.150640

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sarma, P. K. (2022). Farmer Behavior Towards Pesticide Use for Reduction Production Risk: A Theory of Planned Behavior. Clean. Circular Bioeconomy 1, 100002. doi:10.1016/j.clcb.2021.100002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sharafi, K., Pirsaheb, M., Maleki, S., Arfaeinia, H., Karimyan, K., Moradi, M., et al. (2018). Knowledge, Attitude and Practices of Farmers About Pesticide Use, Risks, and Wastes; A Cross-Sectional Study (Kermanshah, Iran). Sci. Total Environ. 645, 509–517. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.07.132

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sharma, A., Shukla, A., Attri, K., Kumar, M., Kumar, P., Suttee, A., et al. (2020). Global Trends in Pesticides: A Looming Threat and Viable Alternatives. Ecotoxicol. Environ. Saf. 201, 110812. doi:10.1016/j.ecoenv.2020.110812

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Silva, V., Mol, H. G. J., Zomer, P., Tienstra, M., Ritsema, C. J., and Geissen, V. (2019). Pesticide Residues in European Agricultural Soils - A Hidden Reality Unfolded. Sci. Total Environ. 653, 1532–1545. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.10.441

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Song, M., Zhao, X., and Shang, Y. (2020). The Impact of Low-Carbon City Construction on Ecological Efficiency: Empirical Evidence from Quasi-Natural Experiments. Resour. Conservation Recycl. 157, 104777. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2020.104777

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sun, B. W. (2020). Multidimensional Effect Analysis and Mechanism Test of Agricultural Subsidy Policy in China. Reform 318 (8), 102

Google Scholar

Sun, L. H. (2018). Regional Pesticide Packaging Waste Recycling: Farmer’s Choice and Influencing Factors-Comparative Analysis Based on Three Typical Regional Models. J. Heilongjiang Bayi Agric. Univ. 30 (3), 113. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1002-2090.2018.3.020

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tang, L., Luo, X. F., and Zhang, J. B. (2021). Environmental Policies and Farmers’ Environmental Behaviors: Administrative Restriction or Economic Incentive. China Popul. Res. Environ. 31 (6), 147–157. doi:10.12062/cpre.20200939

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Trujillo-Barrera, A., Pennings, J. M. E., and Hofenk, D. (2016). Understanding Producers' Motives for Adopting Sustainable Practices: The Role of Expected Rewards, Risk Perception and Risk Tolerance. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 43, 359–382. doi:10.1093/erae/jbv038

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Vu, H. T., Tran, D., Goto, D., and Kawata, K. (2020). Does Experience Sharing Affect Farmers' Pro-Environmental Behavior? A Randomized Controlled Trial in Vietnam. World Dev. 136, 105062. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105062

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, B., Li, M., Wen, X. Y., Yang, Y. K., Zhu, J. P., Belzile, N., et al. (2020). Distribution Characteristics, Potential Contribution, and Management Strategy of Crop Straw and Livestock-Poultry Manure in Multi-Ethnic Regions of China: A Critical Evaluation. J. Clean. Prod. 274, 123174. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.123174

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, B., Ren, C. Y., Dong, X. Y., Zhang, B., and Wang, Z. H. (2019). Determinants Shaping Willingness towards On-Line Recycling Behaviour: An Empirical Study of Household E-Waste Recycling in China. Resour. Conservation Recycl. 143, 218–225. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2019.01.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, Y. D., Liang, J. P., Yang, J., Ma, X. X., Li, X. Q., Wu, J., et al. (2019). Analysis of the Environmental Behavior of Farmers for Non-Point Source Pollution Control and Management: An Integration of the Theory of Planned Behavior and the Protection Motivation Theory. J. Environ. Manag. 237, 15–23. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2019.02.070

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wąs, A., Malak-Rawlikowska, A., Zavalloni, M., Viaggi, D., Kobus, P., and Sulewski, P. (2021). In Search of Factors Determining the Participation of Farmers in Agri-Environmental Schemes - Does Only Money Matter in Poland? Land Use Policy 101, 105190. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2020.105190

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wei, D., and Du, Z. X. (2018). Farmers’ Willingness to Participate in the Recycling of Pesticide Packaging Waste and its Influencing Factors-An Empirical Analysis Based on Logistic and Semi Logarithmic Model. World Agric. 01, 109. doi:10.13856/j.cn11-1097/s.2018.01.017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wei, X., and Jin, S. Q. (2014). Collecting Pesticide Packaging Wastes: Practices in. Shanghai. Rev. Econ. Res. 59, 70.

Google Scholar

Wen, S. Y., Jia, Z. J., and Chen, X. Q. (2022). Can Low-carbon City Pilot Policies Significantly Improve Carbon Emission Efficiency? Empirical Evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 346, 131131. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.131131

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xi, J. P. (2019). Promote the Construction of China’s Ecological Civilization to a New Stage, 03. Qiushi. Available at: http://www.qstheory.cn/dukan/qs/2019-01/31/c_1124054331.htm (Accessed January 31, 2019).

Google Scholar

Xie, H., Cheng, L., and Lv, T. (2017). Factors Influencing Farmer Willingness to Fallow Winter Wheat and Ecological Compensation Standards in a Groundwater Funnel Area in Hengshui, Hebei Province, China. Sustainability 9, 839. doi:10.3390/su9050839

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. B., Zhang, Z. Y., Kuang, Y. J., Li, C., Sun, M. X., Zhang, L. X., et al. (2021). Waste Pesticide Bottles Disposal in Rural China: Policy Constraints and Smallholder Farmers' Behavior. J. Clean. Prod. 316, 128385. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128385

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yang, X. M., Wang, F., Meng, L., Zhang, W. S., Fan, L. X., Geissen, V., et al. (2014). Farmer and Retailer Knowledge and Awareness of the Risks from Pesticide Use: A Case Study in the Wei River Catchment, China. Sci. Total Environ. 497-498, 172–179. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2014.07.118

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, C., Hu, R. F., Shi, G. M., Jin, Y. H., Robson, M. G., and Huang, X. S. (2015). Overuse or Underuse? An Observation of Pesticide Use in China. Sci. Total Environ. 538, 1–6. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2015.08.031

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, L. G., Li, X. R., Yu, J. L., and Yao, X. L. (2018). Toward Cleaner Production: What Drives Farmers to Adopt Eco-Friendly Agricultural Production? J. Clean. Prod. 184, 550–558. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.02.272

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, P. (2019). China Has Launched a Crucial Battle to Combat Pollution in Rural Areas. Ecol. Econ. 35 (1), 9.

Google Scholar

Zhao, Y. H., and Zhou, H. (2021). Can Social Trust and Policy of Rewards and Punishments Promote Farmers’ Participation in the Recycling of Pesticide Packaging Waste? J. Arid. Land Res. Environ. 35 (4), 17.

Google Scholar

Zhou, Z. F., Liu, J. H., Zeng, H. X., Zhang, T., and Chen, X. H. (2020). How Does Soil Pollution Risk Perception Affect Farmers' Pro-Environmental Behavior? The Role of Income Level. J. Environ. Manag. 270, 110806. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2020.110806

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zorpas, A. A., Lasaridi, K., Pociovalisteanu, D. M., and Loizia, P. (2018). Monitoring and Evaluation of Prevention Activities Regarding Household Organics Waste from Insular Communities. J. Clean. Prod. 172, 3567–3577. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.03.155

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zorpas, A. A., Voukkali, I., and Loizia, P. (2017). “Socio Economy Impact in Relation to Waste Prevention,” in Sustainable Economic Development: Green Economy & Green Growth. Editors W. L. Filho, D. M. Pociovalisteanu, and A. Q. Al-Amin (Switzerland: Springer, International Publishing), 31–48. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-45081-0_2

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zyoud, S. e. H., Sawalha, A. F., Sweileh, W. M., Awang, R., Al-Khalil, S. I., Al-Jabi, S. W., et al. (2010). Knowledge and Practices of Pesticide Use Among Farm Workers in the West Bank, Palestine: Safety Implications. Environ. Health. Prev. Med. 15, 252–261. doi:10.1007/s12199-010-1036-310.1007/s12199-010-0136-3

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: pesticide packaging waste recycling, policies intervention, farmers, game theory, PSM model

Citation: Hu N, Zhang Q, Li C and Sun H (2022) Policy Intervention Effect Research on Pesticide Packaging Waste Recycling: Evidence From Jiangsu, China. Front. Environ. Sci. 10:922711. doi: 10.3389/fenvs.2022.922711

Received: 18 April 2022; Accepted: 24 May 2022;
Published: 08 July 2022.

Edited by:

Antonis A. Zorpas, Open University of Cyprus, Cyprus

Reviewed by:

Hua Lu, Jiangxi University of Finance and Economics, China
Dingqiang Sun, Nanjing Agricultural University, China
Iliana Papamichael, Open University of Cyprus, Cyprus

Copyright © 2022 Hu, Zhang, Li and Sun. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Hongwu Sun, Sunhwjaas@163.com

These authors have contributed equally to this work and share first authorship

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.