Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Environ. Sci., 23 June 2022
Sec. Environmental Economics and Management
This article is part of the Research Topic Economic Development, Social Consequences, and Technological Innovation Under Climate Change COVID-19 Pandemic Conditions View all 48 articles

Green Supply Chain Coordination During the COVID-19 Pandemic Based on Consignment Contract

Yi Wang
Yi Wang1*Geovanny Genaro Reivan OrtizGeovanny Genaro Reivan Ortiz2William Dextre-Martinez&#x;William Dextre-Martinez3Liandi ZhangLiandi Zhang1
  • 1College of Science, Tianjin University of Commerce, Tianjin, China
  • 2Laboratory of Basic Psychology, Behavioral Analysis and Programmatic Development PAD-LAB, Catholic University of Cuenca, Cuenca, Ecuador
  • 3School of Management and Tourism, Universidad Nacional Santiago Antúnez de Mayolo, Huaraz, Peru

COVID-19 has further strengthened consumers’ online consumption habits and brought a new boom in which enterprises can use online transactions and green products to avoid risk and gain profits in the pandemic. A green supply chain model is established containing one e-commerce platform and one manufacturer. The Nash bargaining contract and Rubinstein bargaining contract are applied to mitigate conflicts of profits in the model. From the coordination analysis, we show that both Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts can achieve coordination and mitigate conflict of profits through the adjustment of platform usage rates. According to each member’s bargaining power and patience, the optimal platform usage rate is determined, the supply chain profits of both sides are allocated, the green production’s research and development are promoted, and a win-win situation is realized. Specifically, in the Nash bargaining contract, the excess profit of each member depends on their bargaining power. The stronger the bargaining power, the more excess profits will go to the e-commerce platform, and the less excess profits will go to the manufacturer. In the Rubinstein bargaining contract, the excess profit of each member depends on the lowest profit bound and bargaining patience. The higher the manufacturer’s (or e-commerce platform’s) patience, the higher his profit. When the patience of both is high (or low), the e-commerce platform (or the manufacturer) plays a leading role and obtains more profits.

Introduction

With population growth, the contradiction among economic development, resource utilization, and environmental protection has become increasingly prominent. A great deal of enterprises are only concerned about economic interests and ignore ecological protection, resulting in the increasingly severe problem of environmental pollution. According to the current population growth trend, the world population will reach 9.8 billion by 2050. The continuous growth of the population has brought a great burden to the Earth, while the energy crisis and environmental pollution will in turn affect human survival. How can awareness be raised to protect the Earth and the environment? In 1970, the United States first proposed “World Earth Day,” which was the first large-scale environmental protection movement in human history. World Earth Day has been held 52 times with different topics until 2021. The purpose is to raise public awareness of environmental protection and advocate for sustainable development. Environmental protection needs everyone to participate. Whether individuals, enterprises, or governments, all can become green concept advocates and practitioners in promoting green action to protect the Earth on which we live. At present, the development of production and living favors are mostly integrated into environmental protection. Because of the outbreak of COVID-19, the economies of all countries and the lives of all people are affected. To reduce exposure, slow down the spread, and minimize the impact of COVID-19, consumers prefer to use online shopping platforms instead of physical stores, which indirectly affects the competition among enterprises. Amid the COVID-19 pandemic, everyone has realized the convenience of the era of the network period and the importance of online communication, especially online shopping. It not only changed people’s lifestyle, but also brought uncertainty to the world’s economic development. Deeply affected by COVID-19, more and more people worldwide have to use online shopping platforms to meet their daily needs, such as, Amazon, eBay, Wish, Alibaba, etc. Since it is difficult for physical stores to maintain economic profits, many manufacturers choose to sell through online platforms to combat COVID-19.

To investigate the performance of online shopping, the usual method is to establish an economic model containing all participants. To mitigate conflicts of interests in an established model, coordination under consignment contracts appears particularly important. The Nash bargaining contract and Rubinstein bargaining contract are two favorite cooperation contracts in characterizing the problem. In 1950, the Nash equilibrium was first proposed by John Forbes Nash in his doctoral thesis (Nash, 1950a). This is an equilibrium analysis theory of non-cooperative game, which reveals the internal relationship between game equilibrium and economic equilibrium. It has a significant impact on game theory and economics, and the 1994 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences was awarded to Nash (Nash, 1950b; Nash, 1951; Nash, 1953). In 1982, Ariel Rubinstein simulated the basic and indefinite complete information bargaining process with the method of complete information dynamic game, and established a complete information alternating bidding bargaining model, which is called the Rubinstein bargaining model (Rubinstein, 1982). Enterprises sell their green products via e-commerce platforms, sharing profits with e-commerce platforms through Nash or Rubinstein consignment contracts. In the contract, e-commerce platforms will gain profits from manufacturers in using his platform.

Benefitted from the Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts, partners will make joint efforts to cooperate in a model to reach a win-win state, which will promote sustainable development of the global economy. For sustainable development, countries have strengthened the management and restriction on enterprises’ environmental problems. Therefore, environmental issues have also become a problem for the development of enterprises. Only enterprises that comply with the green era can have sustainable competitiveness in the face of fierce competition. To deal with the effect of a competitive environment and technological innovation, enterprises have to explore cooperative opportunities to survive in a competitive market. The supply and demand relationship between enterprises constitutes a supply chain, and their cooperation between enterprises generates the mode named supply chain management. How to get the optimal decisions of the sharing ratio among each member be achieved through Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts? This can be solved by green supply chain management, which is a very practical issue worth studying.

The supply chain combined with “environmental protection” and “green” is called a green supply chain, which aims to lower the waste of resources, reduce environmental pollution, and lessen production costs. Governments worldwide have made great efforts in encouraging enterprises to produce green products. For example, China determined to achieve low-carbon life by implementing limitations of carbon dioxide emissions. In 2030, an emission peak will be reached; in 2060, carbon neutrality will be accomplished. Environmental protection not only has attracted increasing attention of enterprises, but also draws the attention of consumers looking to buy green food. The question of how to obtain optimal profits, reduce manufacturing costs, and minimize environmental pollution becomes the critical point of supply chain management.

In this paper, we established a model of green products under consignment contracts in. Comparing to the current results, we have the following contributions. Firstly, we investigated effects under consignment contracts on green supply chain performance, greenness, and prices of green products. Secondly, by using Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts, we coordinated the supply chain. Thirdly, through a coordination mechanism, we redistributed profits of supply chain members to promote the sustainable development of green products and a win-win situation for two parties.

Literature Review

We reviewed the related literature in three topics: the game model based on consignment contracts, the green supply chain model, and the coordination of the green supply chain.

Game Model Based on Consignment Contracts

The development trend of economic globalization and the trade scale of the global economy urgently need a new economic operation mode and business operation mode. In the background of economic globalization, how can a global strategy be implemented to improve one’s viability and competitiveness, and overcome constraints of space and time? Organizations such as modern enterprises, merchants, and state machines must seek and adopt new development models. This brings the development of e-commerce platforms. A consignment contract, as a legal provision, standardizes the consumer market, and attracts the attention of researchers. Researchers have made great efforts in coordinating models by the Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts.

Li et al. (2009) used the Nash bargaining model to analyze a chain model containing two members. They researched conditions to coordinate their supply chain, and gave optimal decisions of their members and whole channel. Yildiz (2011) studied a final-offer arbitration model under the Nash and Rubinstein bargaining game. Adida and Ratisoontorn (2011) set a model of three members under consignment contracts. They found that the contract which most benefits the manufacturer will not be fixed, but for the retailer, the consignment price contract is better than the other two contracts. Hu et al. (2014) investigated an inventory control model on consignment contracts. They gave optimal control strategies and analyzed the vendor’s return policy. Avinadav et al. (2015) focused on a model influenced by risk sensitivity corresponding to mobile applications. They obtained optimal decisions by different risk attitudes, such as averse, neutral, seeking. Guha (2019) searched the performance of malice and patience in the Rubinstein bargaining model. De Giovanni et al. (2019) issued the supply chain management of a marketing-operations interface under a consignment contract. They found that a cooperative program will be beneficial to a retailer, but not good for manufacturers. Zhao et al. (2020) developed a supply chain shelf model on a consignment contract. They presented each member’s optimal decisions in horizontal scenarios, and investigated strategies under horizontal collusion. Zhou et al. (2022) described a competitive model with third-party platform-integration under Nash bargaining. Shi et al. (2021) established a platform supply chain. By Nash game theory, they found that the usage of a platform only benefits partners with low competition, occurring in different four different channels. Xu et al. (2021) constructed a sea-cargo supply chain, and analyzed the impact on their model through the Stackelberg-Nash game. Ye et al. (2021) built a model containing a platform. By Nash game theory, they examined competition between partners, and examined performance in a long-run or short-run. Hasiloglu and Kaya (2021) considered a model containing e-commerce platforms and analyzed the influence of each factor by game theory. Zhang and Wang (2021) (Zhang and Wang, 2021) investigated a sustainable supply chain under the Rubinstein game model. Caparr o s and Pereau (2021) (Caparrós and Pereau, 2021) showed different results in two cooperation negotiating procedures under Rubinstein game theory. Tang et al. (2021a) studied a model under credit term-based contracts. They obtained optimal decisions, and a win-win state was proposed. Ouyang et al. (2021) issued a framework to warn for COVID-19 by some contracts. They found that their framework is beneficial in decentralized decision-making channels. Avinadav et al. (2022) searched a model of an app developer and a distributer, and analyzed their revenue sharing by a consignment contract.

Green Supply Chain Model

For application in actual production, various models have been built to investigate optimal decisions. For example, Ghosh and Shah (2015) researched the optimal solutions in a model under different contracts. Xu et al. (2016) investigated the optimal strategy for each link in a three-tier chain model when the green level of upstream suppliers affects the carbon emissions of the core manufacturer. Cao and Liu (2017) investigated the feasibility of proactive implementation in a supply chain model without government incentives under information asymmetry. They demonstrated the superiority of cooperative decision-making under information asymmetry by comparing games of whether or not to cooperate. Zhang et al. (2017) established a model due to consumer strategy behavior for three cases: no government subsidy, a government subsidy to the green product manufacturer, or to the green consumer, and the study showed that government subsidy to the green product manufacturer is more beneficial to the development of green products. Sinayi and Rasti-Barzoki (2018) studied optimal product price, greenness, and social welfare strategies for green supply chains under government intervention. Wen et al. (2018) constructed a model considering consumers’ green preferences and intervention by governments.

Coordination of Green Supply Chain

To seek maximization in a decentralized channel’s overall profits, as well as the maximization of members’ profits, the channel’s cooperation is the standard method to achieve this goal. Researchers have made great efforts in coordinating different models.

Seifert et al. (2012) established a model of three parties: supplier, manufacturer, and retailer. They analyzed coordination of the supply chain in price-contracts. They found that distinguishing between two sub-supply chains equals the transfer of the channel’s shortage cost. Huo et al. (2015) studied a model and tested it with 617 manufacturers. They researched the effect of IT and inter-organizational relationship on coordination capability. Hu et al. (2018) investigated whether different contracts can coordinate their supply chain. Results showed that a conventional option contract will not coordinate the model. Xu et al. (2020) issued a supply chain coordination corresponding of online platforms by cost-sharing contracts. Whether or not the model can be coordinated depends on the factors, such as contracts, delivery time sensitivity, and platform power. Chandra and Vipin (2021) researched a vaccine supply chain by coordinating contracts. The results showed that their supply chain cannot be coordinated by a wholesale price contract. Tang et al. (2021b) researched a coordination of carbon taxation among enterprises and consumers. Song et al. (2022) explored a model containing two different products. They analyzed optimal decisions, and showed contracts in coordinating their model. Qiu et al. (2022) investigated O2O supply chain coordination. A comparison showed among three kinds of contracts in coordinating their model. Overall a large extent of literature considers different attributes of COVID-19, such as socio-economic impacts (Irfan et al., 2021; Ahmad et al., 2022), environmental consequences (Razzaq et al., 2020; Irfan et al., 2022; Razzaq et al., 2022), and logistics operations (Khan et al., 2021a; Yu et al., 2021), and few studies generally discuss industry 4.0 practices at the firm level (Khan et al., 2021b), and other investment factors (Razzaq et al., 2021). However, little is known regarding the proposed relationship.

Under the pandemic, the online transaction has become a mainstream consumption mode. Compared to the reviewed literature streams, we extended the research area of the green supply chain in combining the e-commerce platform and green product manufacturer. We described two partners’ decisions in two structures (centralized and decentralized channel), and introduced Nash and Rubinstein bargaining consignment contracts in coordinating the decentralized chain.

Description of the Problem

The model in our paper contains a green product manufacturer and an e-commerce platform. Referring to Savaskan et al. (2004), this paper assumes market demand  q(q>0) as a linear function of product price p and greenness θ. Let q(p,θ)=abp+αθ, where α(α>0) is the potential market demand, implying that consumers prefer cheaper production with high greenness. Referring to the study of Zhu and Dou (2011), this paper assumes that research and development investment is a quadratic function of its greenness Iθ2, with I(I>0) the green investment parameter. The manufacturer undertakes research and development costs. Referring to Luo et al. (2017), a significant difference of the e-commerce platform consignment model and the traditional wholesale and retail model shows that the manufacturer decides productions’ price and greenness, and e-commerce platform charges the manufacturer a certain platform usage fee, i.e., a certain percentage λ (0 < λ < 1) of the revenue from the sale of the green product. The marketing cost of an e-commerce platform denotes as c(a>bc>0). Figure 1 is the structure of our model.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. Structure of the supply chain model.

Game Model Under Consignment Contracts

Channel Performance With Centralized Decision-Making

Under a centralized channel, two members perform as one form in deciding optimal decisions to maximize the channel’s total profits. The whole channel’s profit is:

ΠC(p,θ)=(pc)(abp+αθ)Iθ2.(1)

By optimizing Eq. 1, the following Theorem 1 is obtained.

THEOREM 1. When α2<4bI, the optimal greenness, price, and total channel’s profit under the centralized decision are, respectively:

pc=2I(abc)4bIα2+c,θc=α(abc)4bIα2,ΠC∗=I(abc)24bIα2.

Proof By the first-order optimality conditions,

ΠCp=a2bp+αθ+bc=0,ΠCθ=2=0.

We have

pc=2I(abc)4bIα2+c,θc=α(abc)4bIα2.(2)

Let A1=2ΠCp2=2b, B1=2ΠCθp=α, C1=2ΠCθ2=2I. Since A1<0 and A1B1C12=4bIα2>0, so Eq. 2 is the optimal solution. Finally, substituting pc and θc into Eq. 1, we get the optimal channel’s profit Πc.Next, we aim to investigate the optimal decisions in the decentralized channel.

Channel Performance With Decentralized Decision-Making

In a decentralized model, partners all aim to maximize self-interest. The leadership of the model is an e-commerce platform, and followership is the manufacturer. Firstly, this e-commerce platform determines the usage rate; Secondly, the manufacturer decides the production’s price and greenness after being informed of the usage rate determined by the platform.

For given platform usage rate λ, the manufacturer has profit:

ΠdM(p,θ;λ)=(1λ)p(abp+αθ)Iθ2.(3)

Meanwhile, for any given price p and greenness θ, e-commerce platform holds profit:

ΠdR(λ;p,θ)=λp(abp+αθ)c(abp+αθ).(4)

In the framework of the Stackelberg game, maximizing Eqs 3, 4, Theorem 2 is obtained.

THEOREM 2. When α2<4bI, the optimal price and greenness of the product under the decentralized channel are:

pd=2aIcα22(4bIα2),θd=α2(abc)2abIα(4bIα2).

The optimal usage rate for the platform is:

λd=(2aI+cα2)(4bIα2)α2(2aIcα2).

Manufacturer’s optimal profit is

ΠdM∗=aI[α2(abc)2abI]α2(4bIα2),

and e-commerce platform has profit

ΠdR∗=b(2aIcα2)24α2(4bIα2).

Proof By reasoning process, we first consider the case that manufacturer first decides price and greenness by maximizing its corporate profit based on the platform usage rate determined by the e-commerce platform, whose optimization problem is:

maxp,θΠdM(p,θ|λ).

The first-order optimality condition yields:

ΠdMp=(1λ)(a2bp+αθ)=0,ΠdMθ=(1λ)2=0.

Let A2=2ΠdMp2=2b(1λ), B2=2ΠdMpθ=(1λ)α, C2=2ΠdMθ2=2I. It is known that when 4bIα2>0,A2C2B22=(1λ)[4bI(1λ)α2]>0 and A2<0, there exists a unique optimal solution:

pd(λ)=2aI4bI(1λ)α2 ,θd(λ)=(1λ)4bI(1λ)α2.(5)

Substituting Eq. 5 into Eqs 3, 4, the optimal profit for two members is respectively:

ΠdM=a2 I(1λ)4bI(1λ)α2,  ΠdR(λ)=2abI{2aIλc[4bI(1λ)α2]}[4bI(1λ)α2]2.

Second, consider the first stage of the Stackelberg game, when the e-commerce platform aims to maximize its profit, and its optimization problem is

maxλ ΠdR(λ).

According to the first-order condition in optimizing λ:

dΠdR=A[4bI(1λ)α2]3=0,

with A=2abI[(2aI+cα2)(4bIα2)],B=2abIα2(2aIcα2), we have

λd=(2aI+cα2)(4bIα2)α2(2aIcα2).

By second-order condition,

d2ΠdRdλ2=8a2bI2α2[4bI(1λ)α2]4<0.

Therefore, λd is the unique optimal solution, which leads to Theorem 2.The following proposition is easy to follow.

PROPOSITION 1. pc>pd,θ>θd,ΠC∗>ΠbM∗+ΠbR∗.Proof: Because pcpd=4bcI+2aIcα22(4bIα2)>0, so pc  >pd. Because θc  θd=2abIα(4bIα2)>0, so θc>θd. Because ΠC∗(ΠdM∗+ΠdR∗)=bc2α2(4bIα2)+4a2bI24α2(4bIα2)>0, so ΠC∗>ΠdM∗+ΠdR∗.By Proposition 1, selling price, greenness, and total profits are all higher in the centralized channel than the decentralized one. Since the two parties all pursue the maximization of their profit, it will inevitably create a conflict of interest between them, and goes against the interest of the research and development of green production, so it is essential to establish a coordination contract to raise the partners’ profits.

Coordination Based on Consignment Contracts

Decision-making in a decentralized channel reduces total profit compared with the centralized channel. To mitigate conflicts between partners, it is crucial to establish coordination contracts to optimize the performance of the entire supply chain.

Nash Bargaining Contract

To win more profits for supply chain members, we first take the Nash bargaining contract. Let x be the portion received in total profits by the e-commerce platform. Thus, the manufacturer undertakes the remaining (1x) portion (0x1). Then the profit of the total channel should be

maxxϵ[0,1]f(x)=(xΠC∗ΠdR∗)μ[(1x)ΠC∗ΠdM∗]1μ,

with μϵ[0,1] as the bargaining power of platforms. If μ=0, then the manufacturer has absolute bargaining power; if μ=1, then platforms have absolute bargaining power; if μ=0.5, then both two members have equal bargaining power. Through bargaining, both manufacturer and e-commerce platforms aim to get more profits than the decentralized situation. Note that the optimal solution is

x=μ(ΠCΠdMΠdR)+ΠdRΠC,

and we will get the following result.

PROPOSITION 2. By the Nash bargaining contract, the optimal profits of each member are:

ΠnM∗=aI[α2(abc)2abI]α2(4bIα2)+(1μ)b[c2α2(4bIα2)+4a2I2]4α2(4bIα2),(6)
ΠnR∗=b(2aIcα2)24α2(4bIα2)+μb[c2α2(4bIα2)+4a2I2]4α2(4bIα2).(7)

THEOREM 3. By the Nash bargaining contract, when a>2bc, the optimal platform usage rate is:

λn=(4bIα2){(2aI+cα2)28bc2Iα2+μ[c2α2(4bIα2)+4a2I2]}8Iα2(abc)(2aIcα2+2bcI).(8)

Proof: Substitute pn=pc and θn=θc into Eq. 3. When it equals Eq. 6, we get the optimal platform usage rate as Eq. 8 in the case a>2bc.Under certain conditions, the Nash bargaining contract can raise both members’ profit, which coordinates better than the decentralized channel. Since λn is the optimal decision, this ensures a win-win situation. Regarding the excess profit, it will depend on the members’ bargaining power.

Rubinstein Bargaining Contract

Nash bargaining ends in negotiations between manufacturers and e-commerce platforms in one stage. However, in practice, every member can make a bargain by rejecting a previous idea and creating a new offer. Therefore, Rubinstein bargaining contracts come to this stage. More specifically, the manufacturer and e-commerce platforms take turns quoting the channel profit of the centralized decision. They will not reach an agreement until a mutually satisfactory distribution plan is obtained.

Suppose the manufacturer first proposes a distribution scheme (ΠC∗y,y), and then the e-commerce platform decides to accept or reject it. If he accepts it, this process ends; if the platform rejects the plan, he will propose a new distribution scheme in stage 2, and the manufacturer makes a decision. If he accepts, the negotiation process ends; if he refuses, he will propose a new distribution scheme plan in the third period, and so on, until the two parties reach a consensus distribution scheme. Since patience is limited in the negotiation process, it is assumed that the discount factor of the manufacturer is δM, and the platform is δR, which is determined by patience of negotiating parties. Under the decentralized channel, each member can obtain at least profits ΠdM∗ and ΠdR∗, which is the lowest bound of the bargaining scheme. The following starts from the finite-term situation (the game is played in 1, 2, and 3 stages):

If the negotiation process ends in stage 1, by the optimal principle, then the manufacturer will propose the distribution scheme as (ΠC∗ΠdR∗,ΠdR∗), implying that the manufacturer’s optimal profit is ΠC∗ΠdR∗, and the e-commerce platform undertakes ΠdR∗.

If the negotiation is carried out in stage 2, after the first negotiation in stage 1, the manufacturer can no longer propose a distribution scheme. Meanwhile, the e-commerce platform will propose (ΠdM∗,ΠC∗ΠdM∗) in stage 2. The e-commerce platform’s profit is equivalent to δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗) in stage 1. In stage 1, the e-commerce platform can get profit distributed by the manufacturer of no less than ΠR(2)=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)}. This results in the optimal decision in stage 2, that is, (ΠC∗ΠR(2),ΠR(2)).

PROPOSITION 3.

1) If δRΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗, then ΠR(2)=ΠdR∗, the optimal results in stage 1 and stage 2 are the same

2) If δR>ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗, then ΠR(2)=δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)>ΠdR∗. Compared to the results of stage 1, the manufacturer will obtain less profit, but the e-commerce platform will get more;

If the negotiation is carried out in stage 3, then we will deduce the result reversely. First, in stage 3, the manufacturer will provide the scheme  (ΠC∗ΠdR∗,ΠdR∗), which is equal to the profit in stage 2, say δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗). Since the e-commerce platform in stage 2 set the distribution scheme as  max{ΠdM∗,δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗)}, they will obtain the profit ΠC∗max{ΠdM∗,δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗)}. This is equal to the profit δR(ΠC∗max{ΠdM∗,δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗)}) in stage 1. Therefore, when in stage 1, the manufacturer will set e-commerce platform’s profit no less than ΠR(3)=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗max{ΠdM∗, δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗)})}. Then in Rubinstein bargaining contract of stage 3, the optimal distribution scheme is (ΠC∗ΠR(3),ΠR(3)).

PROPOSITION 4.

1) If δMΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, δRΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗ or δM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, δMδRδRΠC∗ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, then ΠR(3)=ΠdR∗, implying that the distribution scheme in stage 3 is the same as stage 1

2) If δMΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗,δR>ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗, then ΠR(3)=δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)>ΠdR∗. Compared with scheme in stage 1, the manufacturer gets more profit, but the e-commerce platform gets less profit

3) If δM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, δMδR<δRΠC∗ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, then ΠR(3)=δR(ΠC∗δM(ΠC∗ΠdR∗))>ΠdR∗. Compared to results in stage 1, the manufacturer obtains fewer profits, but the e-commerce platforms hold greater profits.

If negotiating indefinitely, then the e-commerce platform has profit y=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗max{ΠdM∗, δM(ΠC∗y)})}. This is because of the subgame is isomorphic to the whole bargaining game.

THEOREM 4.

1) If

δMΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗,δRΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗ or δM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗,δMδRδRΠC∗ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗

, then the distribution scheme of indefinite Rubinstein bargaining contract is (ΠC∗ΠdR∗,ΠdR∗), and the platform usage rate is λRB=(4bIα2)[(2aI+cα2)2+8cIα2(abc)]8Iα2(abc)(2aIcα2+2bcI) 

2) IfδMδRδMΠC∗ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗,  δR>ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗, then the distribution scheme of the indefinite Rubinstein bargaining contract is (ΠC∗δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗),δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)), and the platform usage rate is λRB=δR(4bIα2)[a(2aI+cα2)+bc2α2]2α2(abc)(2aIcα2+2bcI)

3) If δM(1δR)1δRδM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗,  δR(1δM)1δRδM>ΠdR∗ΠC∗, then the distribution scheme of the indefinite Rubinstein bargaining contract is (1δR1δRδMΠC∗,δR(1δM)1δRδMΠC∗), and the platform usage rate is λRB=(4bIα2)[δR(1δM)(abc)+2bc(1δRδM)]2b(2aIcα2+2bcI)(1δRδM).

Proof: For y=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗max{ΠdM∗,δM(ΠC∗y)})}, if ΠdM∗δM(ΠC∗y), then y=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)}; if ΠdR∗δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗), then y=ΠdR∗, and hence δMΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, δRΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗. Set pRB=pc, θRB=θc, the optimal platform usage rate is λRB=(4bIα2)[(2aI+cα2)2+8cIα2(abc)]8Iα2(abc)(2aIcα2+2bcI).If ΠdR∗<δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗), then y=δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗), and hence δMδRδMΠC∗ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗, δR>ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdM∗. Set pRB=pc and θRB=θc, we get the platform usage rate λRB=δR(4bIα2)[a(2aI+cα2)+bc2α2]2α2(abc)(2aIcα2+2bcI).If ΠdM∗<δM(ΠC∗y), then y=max{ΠdR∗,δR(ΠC∗δM(ΠC∗y))}; if ΠdR∗δR(ΠC∗δM(ΠC∗y)), then y=ΠdR∗, and hence δM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗, δMδRδRΠC∗ΠdR∗ΠC∗ΠdR∗; if ΠdR∗<δR(ΠC∗δM(ΠC∗y)), then y=δR(ΠC∗δM(ΠC∗y)), that is, y=δR(1δM)1δRδMΠC∗. Then δM(1δR)1δRδM>ΠdM∗ΠC∗, δR(1δM)1δRδM>ΠdR∗ΠC∗. Set pRB=pc and θRB=θc, then the platform usage rate is λRB=(4bIα2)[δR(1δM)(abc)+2bc(1δRδM)]2b(2aIcα2+2bcI)(1δRδM).The Rubinstein bargaining contract can perfectly coordinate our supply chain. The optimal platform usage rate and distribution scheme of channel profits depend on the lower profit limit and patience of each member. In this case, members’ profits can be guaranteed. When the patience of each member is weak or the manufacturer’s patience performs higher than some threshold, the optimal decision of manufacturer and platform is (ΠC∗ΠdR∗,ΠdR∗); when the patience of the manufacturer increases and platform’s patience is higher than some threshold, then optimal allocation is (ΠC∗δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗),δR(ΠC∗ΠdM∗)); when the patience of each member is high enough, then the manufacturer and e-commerce platform will press proportional profit distribution, the optimal distribution is (1δR1δRδMΠC∗,δR(1δM)1δRδMΠC∗).

Case Study

In this section, the previous theoretical analysis is verified through numerical calculations and managerial insights. Set a=1000, b=50, c=6, I=10, α=40. Table 1 shows results of optimal profit and optimal solution under different models.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Optimal profit and optimal solutions under different models.

Data in Table 1 verifies that price, greenness, and total profit in centralized channels are all higher compared to the decentralized one. This is a motivation to find a method to coordinate the decentralized channel in reaching the centralized channel’s profit. At the same time, every member obtains more than the lowest profit bound, that is, the profit in the decentralized channel. Under the Nash bargaining coordination contract, the platform usage rate increases in bargaining power μ. Excess profit depends on bargaining power. When the bargaining power increases, profit of the e-commerce platform increases, but the profit of the manufacturer decreases. Although the platform usage rate decreases under the Nash bargaining contract, both members obtained more profits than the decentralized case, achieving a win-win state. Under the Rubinstein bargaining coordination contract, the decentralized channel can also be coordinated. Each member’s profit depends on the lowest profit bound and bargaining patience:

1) When the manufacturer is very patient, that is, δM=1, no matter how the e-commerce platform’s patience changes, the manufacturer plays a leading role in obtaining the most profit. Still, the e-commerce platform holds the same profit as in the decentralized channel. This is consistent with the first profit distribution scheme of Theorem 4.

2) When the e-commerce platform performs very patiently, i.e., δR=1, they will get the most profit regardless of how the manufacturer’s patience changes. In contrast, the manufacturer obtains the same profit as in the decentralized channel, which is consistent with the second profit distribution scheme of Theorem 4.

3) When the patience of both sides of the game is higher (less than 1), two members will distribute profits proportionally, which is consistent with the third profit distribution scheme of Theorem 4. In this case, as the patience of both sides increases, the e-commerce platform’s patience increases, while the manufacturer’s profit decreases, showing that the e-commerce platform plays a leading role. This implies that the stronger the patience of the two members, the more profit the e-commerce platform will get.

Under the first distribution scheme of the Rubinstein bargaining contract, the manufacturer has the strongest degree of patience and the largest profit, which is consistent with the profit distribution scheme when μ=0 under the Nash bargaining coordination contract. Under the second distribution scheme of the Rubinstein bargaining contract, the e-commerce platform has the strongest degree of patience. His profit is also the largest, and it is consistent with the profit distribution plan when μ=1 under the Nash bargaining coordination contract. Profits of chain members are quite different under the first two distribution plans, but under the third distribution plan, the difference between members is relatively small.

Whether using the Nash or Rubinstein bargaining coordination contract, it all achieved the performance in a centralized channel. Although the platform usage rates of the two bargaining coordination contracts are both lower compared to the decentralized case, they still obtain more profit than the decentralized cases. The platform and the manufacturer get profits shared according to their bargaining power or patience, and their respective profits all come out higher than the decentralized channel. These two contracts coordinate the conflicts well in a decentralized supply chain, which achieves a win-win situation.

Result

During the COVID-19 pandemic, the supply chain has entered a new stage of convergence with e-commerce. Consignment contracts based on electronic markets have become the main development trend of corporate marketing in practice. In our paper, a green supply chain model under consignment contracts is studied. We compare and analyze the effects of a centralized channel and decentralized channel under consignment contracts on price, greenness, and total profit. the centralized channel is beneficial to improve the greenness of products and the profitability of the total supply chain. Not only the price, greenness, and profit of manufacturers are reduced, but also the research and development will be promoted.

In the decentralized channel, the competition of partners will lower the total channel’s profit, and each member’s profit. To improve the profits of chain members, effectively alleviate conflicts of interest between them, and promote the level of research and development, this paper proposes both Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contract of cooperative game to coordinate a chain model. Manufacturers and e-commerce platforms can negotiate prices, enhance coordination awareness, and reallocate overall profits. After determining a new optimal platform usage rate, they can obtain profits that are not lower than those under a decentralized channel, and achieve a win-win situation.

From the coordination analysis, we show that both the Nash and Rubinstein bargaining contracts can achieve coordination through the adjustment of platform usage rates. It can be seen from the numerical calculation that in Nash bargaining, both members in the supply chain will obtain higher profits as their bargaining power improves; in Rubinstein bargaining, the profits shared by both members in the supply chain are closely related to their respective degrees of patience. Compared with the decentralized channel, the e-commerce platform indirectly promotes the manufacturer to increase research and development by reducing platform usage rate, thereby increasing retail price, greenness, and total profits of the channel.

Discussion

This paper discussed green supply chain coordination under bargaining contracts, which contains one e-commerce platform and one manufacturer. The results have practical significance in a socio-economic environment. Partners can obtain profits based on their bargaining power and patience. To get extra profits than the decentralized channel, they can choose a different bargaining contract to benefit themselves. Comparing to Wang et al. (2019), our model added the greenness into discussion, which extended the research area in green supply chain. But there still exist limitations, which will be the topic of future studies.

Limitations and Future Work

1) With regard to the complexity of our model, there are two members: one e-commerce platform and one green manufacturer. But in reality, there may be more participants in the channel. We aim to investigate the optimal decisions in the model, and to coordinate the decentralized channel by consignment contracts.

2) By the assumption of our paper, the model is static, and this can be extended to a dynamic one. Moreover, there exist uncertainty factors in the consumer market, such as product recommendations, credit payment discounts, advertisement, consumer preference, etc., so the demand function can be extended to a stochastic one.

3) In order to encourage the development of the green supply chain, governments across the world have unveiled “Environmental Economic and Policy.” It turns out that the participation of government is very necessary. In our future work, we can consider the participation of government, such as subsidy or tax. Under this circumstance, enterprises will take active participation in greening products, protecting the environment, and achieving a win-win situation.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary Material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author Contributions

YW issued the idea and designed for the research. YW and LZ analyzed the model and drafted the paper. GR and WD-M edited and revised the paper critically.

Funding

This research was supported by the Tianjin Municipal Education Commission (Grant No. 2018KJ229).

Conflict of Interest

All authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank all participants of our paper.

References

Adida, E., and Ratisoontorn, N. (2011). Consignment Contracts with Retail Competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 215, 136–148. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2011.05.059

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ahmad, B., Irfan, M., Salem, S., and Asif, M. H. (2022). Energy Efficiency in the Post-COVID-19 Era: Exploring the Determinants of Energy-Saving Intentions and Behaviors. Front. Energy Res. 9, 824318. doi:10.3389/fenrg.2021.824318

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., and Perlman, Y. (2015). The Effect of Risk Sensitivity on a Supply Chain of Mobile Applications under a Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing and Quality Investment. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 168, 31–40. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2015.05.036

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., Meilijson, I., and Perlman, Y. (2022). A Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing between an App Developer and a Distribution Platform. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 243, 108332. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108322

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cao, Y., and Liu, Z. H. (2017). A Feasible Analysis for Practicing Green Supply Chain Management without Government Policy Incentives. J. Ind. Eng. 31 (2), 119–127.

Google Scholar

Caparrós, B. A., and Pereau, J.-C. (2021). Inefficient Coasean Negotiations over Emissions and Transfers. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 189, 359–378. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2021.06.044

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chandra, D., and Vipin, B. (2021). On the Vaccine Supply Chain Coordination under Subsidy Contract. Vaccine 39, 4039–4045. doi:10.1016/j.vaccine.2021.05.081

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

De Giovanni, P., Karray, S., and Martín-Herrán, G. (2019). Vendor Management Inventory with Consignment Contracts and the Benefits of Cooperative Advertising. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 272, 465–480. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2018.06.031

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ghosh, D., and Shah, J. (2015). Supply Chain Analysis under Green Sensitive Consumer Demand and Cost Sharing Contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 164, 319–329. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.11.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Guha, B. (2019). Malice and Patience in Rubinstein Bargaining. Res. Econ. 73, 264–270. doi:10.1016/j.rie.2019.07.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hasiloglu, M., and Kaya, O. (2021). An Analysis of Price, Service and Commission Rate Decisions in Online Sales Made through E-Commerce Platforms. Comput. Ind. Eng. 162, 107688. doi:10.1016/j.cie.2021.107688

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, W., Li, Y., and Govindan, K. (2014). The Impact of Consumer Returns Policies on Consignment Contracts with Inventory Control. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 233, 398–407. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2013.03.015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, B., Qu, J., and Meng, C. (2018). Supply Chain Coordination under Option Contracts with Joint Pricing under Price-dependent Demand. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 205, 74–86. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2018.08.033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Huo, B., Zhang, C., and Zhao, X. (2015). The Effect of IT and Relationship Commitment on Supply Chain Coordination: A Contingency and Configuration Approach. Inf. Manag. 52, 728–740. doi:10.1016/j.im.2015.06.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Irfan, M., Salem, S., Ahmad, M., Acevedo-Duque, Á., Abbasi, K. R., Ahmad, F., et al. (2021). Interventions for the Current COVID-19 Pandemic: Frontline Workers' Intention to Use Personal Protective Equipment. Front. Public Health 9, 793642. doi:10.3389/fpubh.2021.793642

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Irfan, M., Razzaq, A., Suksatan, W., Sharif, A., Madurai Elavarasan, R., Yang, C., et al. (2022). Asymmetric Impact of Temperature on COVID-19 Spread in India: Evidence from Quantile-On-Quantile Regression Approach. J. Therm. Biol. 104, 103101. doi:10.1016/j.jtherbio.2021.103101

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Khan, S. A. R., Razzaq, A., Yu, Z., Shah, A., Sharif, A., and Janjua, L. (2021). Disruption in Food Supply Chain and Undernourishment Challenges: An Empirical Study in the Context of Asian Countries. Socio-Econ. Plan. Sci. 101033. doi:10.1016/j.seps.2021.101033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Khan, S. A. R., Razzaq, A., Yu, Z., and Miller, S. (2021). Industry 4.0 and Circular Economy Practices: A New Era Business Strategies for Environmental Sustainability. Bus. Strat. Env. 30 (8), 4001–4014. doi:10.1002/bse.2853

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, S., Zhu, Z., and Huang, L. (2009). Supply Chain Coordination and Decision Making under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 120, 88–99. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.07.015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Luo, C. L., Mao, X. B., and Tian, X. (2017). Demand Information Sharing Strategies in Online Platform Selling Mode. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 25 (8), 149–157. doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2017.08.016

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nash, J. F. (1950). Equilibrium Points in N -person Games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 36 (1), 48–49. doi:10.1073/pnas.36.1.48

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nash, J. F. (1950). The Bargaining Problem. Econometrica 18, 155–162. doi:10.2307/1907266

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nash, J. (1951). Non-Cooperative Games. Ann. Math. 54, 286–295. doi:10.2307/1969529

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nash, J. (1953). Two-Person Cooperative Games. Econometrica 21, 128–140. Available at: https://max.book118.com/html/2018/0920/7146056101001150.shtm. doi:10.2307/1906951

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ouyang, L., Yuan, Y., Cao, Y., and Wang, F.-Y. (2021). A Novel Framework of Collaborative Early Warning for COVID-19 Based on Blockchain and Smart Contracts. Inf. Sci. 570, 124–143. doi:10.1016/j.ins.2021.04.021

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Qiu, R., Yu, Y., and Sun, M. (2022). Supply Chain Coordination by Contracts Considering Dynamic Reference Quality Effect under the O2O Environment. Comput. Ind. Eng. 163, 107802. doi:10.1016/j.cie.2021.107802

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Razzaq, A., Sharif, A., Aziz, N., Irfan, M., and Jermsittiparsert, K. (2020). Asymmetric Link between Environmental Pollution and COVID-19 in the Top Ten Affected States of US: A Novel Estimations from Quantile-On-Quantile Approach. Environ. Res. 191, 110189. doi:10.1016/j.envres.2020.110189

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Razzaq, A., An, H., and Delpachitra, S. (2021). Does Technology Gap Increase FDI Spillovers on Productivity Growth? Evidence from Chinese Outward FDI in Belt and Road Host Countries. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 172, 121050. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121050

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Razzaq, A., Cui, Y., Irfan, M., Maneengam, A., and Acevedo-Duque, Á. (2022). Asymmetric Effects of Fine Particulate Matter and Stringency Policy on COVID-19 Intensity. Int. J. Environ. Health Res., 1–13. doi:10.1080/09603123.2022.2059452

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model. Econometrica 50, 97–109. Available at: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1912531?origin=crossref. doi:10.2307/1912531

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Savaskan, R. C., Bhattacharya, S., and Van Wassenhove, L. N. (2004). Closed-loop Supply Chain Models with Product Remanufacturing. Manag. Sci. 50 (2), 239–252. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1030.0186

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Seifert, R. W., Zequeira, R. I., and Liao, S. (2012). A Three-Echelon Supply Chain with Price-Only Contracts and Sub-supply Chain Coordination. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 138, 345–353. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.04.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shi, D., Wang, M., and Li, X. (2021). Strategic Introduction of Marketplace Platform and its Impacts on Supply Chain. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 242, 108300. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108300

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sinayi, M., and Rasti-Barzoki, M. (2018). A Game Theoretic Approach for Pricing, Greening, and Social Welfare Policies in a Supply Chain with Government Intervention. J. Clean. Prod. 196, 1443–1458. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.05.212

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Song, H., Chu, H., Yue, H., and Chen, Y. (2022). Green Supply Chain Coordination with Substitutable Products under Cost Sharing Contract. Procedia Comput. Sci. 199, 1112–1119. doi:10.1016/j.procs.2022.01.141

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tang, W., Li, H., and Cai, K. (2021). Optimising the Credit Term Decisions in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 59 (14), 4324–4341. doi:10.1080/00207543.2020.1762018

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tang, W., Li, H., and Chen, J. (2021). Optimizing Carbon Taxation Target and Level: Enterprises, Consumers, or Both? J. Clean. Prod. 282, 124515. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124515

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, C., Fan, X., and Yin, Z. (2019). Financing Online Retailers: Bank vs. Electronic Business Platform, Equilibrium, and Coordinating Strategy. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 276 (1), 343–356. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2019.01.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wen, X. Q., Cheng, H. F., Cai, J. H., and Lu, C. (2018). Government Subsidies Policies and Effect Analysis in Green Supply Chain. Chin. J. Manag. 15 (4), 625–632. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1672-884x.2018.04.017

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X. H., Luo, Q., and Bai, Q. G. (2016). Optimal Policy with Emission Reducing Effort in Multi-Echelon Green Supply Chain under Cap-And -trade Regulation. Ind. Eng. Manag. 21 (1), 37–44.

Google Scholar

Xu, X., Zhang, M., and He, P. (2020). Coordination of a Supply Chain with Online Platform Considering Delivery Time Decision. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 141, 101990. doi:10.1016/j.tre.2020.101990

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, L., Shi, J., and Chen, J. (2021). Platform Encroachment with Price Matching: Introducing a Self-Constructing Online Platform into the Sea-Cargo Market. Comput. Ind. Eng. 156, 107266. doi:10.1016/j.cie.2021.107266

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ye, F., Ni, D., and Li, K. W. (2021). Competition between Manufacturers and Sharing Economy Platforms: An Owner Base and Sharing Utility Perspective. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 234, 108022. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.108022

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yildiz, M. (2011). Nash Meets Rubinstein in Final-Offer Arbitration. Econ. Lett. 110, 226–230. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2010.10.020

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yu, Z., Razzaq, A., Rehman, A., Shah, A., Jameel, K., and Mor, R. S. (2021). Disruption in Global Supply Chain and Socio-Economic Shocks: a Lesson from COVID-19 for Sustainable Production and Consumption. Oper. Manag. Res., 1–16. doi:10.1007/s12063-021-00179-y

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, C.-T., and Wang, Z. (2021). Production Mode and Pricing Coordination Strategy of Sustainable Products Considering Consumers' Preference. J. Clean. Prod. 296, 126476. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126476

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, Y. L., Hu, X. J., Yang, H. H., and Lu, C. D. (2017). Green Supply Chain Decision Model Based on Government Subsidies and Consumer Strategic Behaviors. Forecasting 36 (2), 57–63. doi:10.11847/fj.36.2.57

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhao, J., Zhou, Y.-W., Cao, Z.-H., and Min, J. (2020). The Shelf Space and Pricing Strategies for a Retailer-Dominated Supply Chain with Consignment Based Revenue Sharing Contracts. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 280, 926–939. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2019.07.074

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhou, Y., Yang, H., Ke, J., Wang, H., and Li, X. (2022). Competition and Third-Party Platform-Integration in Ride-Sourcing Markets. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 159, 76–103. In press. doi:10.1016/j.trb.2021.08.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhu, Q. H., and Dou, Y. J. (2011). A Game for Green Supply Chain Management Based on Government Subsidies. J. Manag. Sci. China 14 (6), 86–95.

Google Scholar

Keywords: COVID-19, green supply chain, consignment contract, sustainable development, environmental sustainability

Citation: Wang Y, Reivan Ortiz GG, Dextre-Martinez W and Zhang L (2022) Green Supply Chain Coordination During the COVID-19 Pandemic Based on Consignment Contract. Front. Environ. Sci. 10:899007. doi: 10.3389/fenvs.2022.899007

Received: 18 March 2022; Accepted: 21 April 2022;
Published: 23 June 2022.

Edited by:

Asif Razzaq, Dalian University of Technology, China

Reviewed by:

Tayyaba Rani, Xi’an Jiaotong University, China
Mohsin Shahzad, Dalian University of Technology, China

Copyright © 2022 Wang, Reivan Ortiz, Dextre-Martinez and Zhang. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Yi Wang, lxywangyi@tjcu.edu.cn

ORCID: William Dextre-Martinez, orcid.org/0000-0003-1481-0584

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.