- College of Economics and Management, Shandong University of Science and Technology, Qingdao, China
An environmental administrative penalty is a powerful tool to regulate environmental pollution and ecological destruction by punishing intentional violations. Still, unchecked discretion may lead to excessively low or high penalties, breaking our balance of desire for uniformity with the need for discretion. To achieve the balance, regulators may use standardized discretion to achieve greater compliance by punishing intentional violations in a standardized way. However, policymakers and scholars have different attitudes on understanding whether standardized discretion helps enforcement. For this purpose, we construct a muti-agent dynamic game under the standardized discretion of environmental administrative penalty (SDEAP). The results show that: i) SDEAP can positively affect firms’ output and emission reduction efforts but negatively affect environmental quality; ii) The lower limit of SDEAP can positively affect environmental quality but negatively affects firms’ output and emission reduction efforts; iii) The upper limit of SDEAP can positively affect firms’ output, emission reduction efforts, and environmental quality; iv) SDEAP can restrict law enforcement and improve firms’ efforts to reduce emissions. This work can be helpful both to firms and the government as the basis for developing and implementing SDEAP.
1 Introduction
Resources shortage and environmental pollution have long restricted the sustainable development of China’s economy (Yu et al., 2020; Kong et al., 2021; Ma et al., 2022; Wang et al., 2022), which requires scientific and practical implementation of environmental regulation policies (Wang & Wang, 2022). However, in the process of environmental regulation, the phenomena that different penalties for the same or similar environmental violations often occur. It causes unfairness (Zhang et al., 2018; Sancho, 2021). Take the cases of Heze City and Weihai City in Shandong Province as examples.
Example 1. Some cases in Heze City in 2013 are shown in Table 1. Article 48 of Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Air Pollution (20001) stipulates that whoever discharges2 pollutants into the atmosphere over the national and local discharge limits shall be fined 10,000–100,000 RMB.
TABLE 1. Cases of environmental administrative penalties in Heze City in 20132.
Example 2. Some cases in Weihai City in 2015 are shown in Table 2. Article 56 of Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Ambient Noise Pollution (19973) stipulates that whoever produces night construction noise in an area where noise pollution is prohibited should be fined.
TABLE 2. Cases of environmental administrative penalties in Weihai City in 20154.
The penalties in these six cases are legal but unfair. In example 1, the penalty amount in Case 2) is much higher than that in Case 3), while the SO2 concentration in Case 2) is lower than that in Case 3). In example 2, Cases (4–6) were penalized differently when they committed the same environmental violations. The broad penalty range gives law enforcers discretionary power. The misuse of discretion causes these unfair phenomena. Still, it is just the tip of the iceberg. Only in 2021, the Chinese government issued more than 55,200 decisions of environmental administrative penalties. The total amount of fines is up to 4.33 billion RMB. The number of cases and fines is enormous. If discretion is not well used, a lot of misuses occur.
Misuses of discretion may breed corruption and unfairness, causing an indelible negative impact. An insufficient penalty is not conducive to eco-environmental protection, while an excessive penalty is not conducive to economic development (Chang et al., 2020). Therefore, the appropriateness and standardization of discretion are crucial (Kochtcheeva, 2010). China took the lead in the standardized discretion of environmental administrative penalty (SDEAP). It is one of the rules specially set to regulate environmental administrative discretion. This regulation system is vital to change the misuse of discretion. Since 2009, the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of China has issued many policies, including the Guidance on Standardizing the Exercise of the Discretion of Environmental Supervision and Law Enforcement, the Reference Guide for Refining the Discretion of Administrative Penalty for Major Environmental Violations, and the Catalogue of Administrative Penalty of Environmental Protection Administration Set by Laws. In 2019, the Ministry of Ecology and Environment issued the Guiding Opinions on Further Standardizing the Discretion of Environmental Administrative Penalty. SDEAP has become a new tool widely used in China’s environmental regulation.
SDEAP aims to solve the problems of broad discretion and misuse of discretion in environmental protection. To explain the SDEAP in further detail, we take the Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Air Pollution as an example. The narrowest penalty range is 500–20,00 RMB. The most comprehensive penalty range is 100,000–1000,000 RMB. The upper limits of the penalties are 4–10 times the lower limits. The penalty range stipulated in the law is overbroad. SDEAP restricts discretion by refining the penalty range. As article 485, the standardized discretion is shown in Table 36.
Table 3 shows how the SDEAP restricts discretion. There are three vital elements in SDEAP: the intensity of standardized discretion and the lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount. The intensity of standardized discretion determines the refinement of discretion. The lower limit of the administrative penalty amount determines the minimum penalty amount. The upper limit of the administrative penalty amount determines the maximum penalty amount. Under SDEAP, violations point to different penalty ranges are refined. Misusing discretion, like in Heze City and Weihai City, will be rare. Other environmental laws like the Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Water Pollution, Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Soil Pollution, Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Ambient Noise Pollution, and Law of the People’s Republic of China on the Prevention and Control of Solid Waste Pollution are the same.
Policymakers and scholars have disagreements on the effect of SDEAP. Policymakers believe that SDEAP could balance eco-environmental protection and economic development and create a fair environment for firms7 and provide an institutional guarantee for China’s high-quality development8. Some scholars are skeptical about the SDEAP. They believe that administrative discretion is the space reserved for law enforcement. It allows officers to adjust penalties as new information becomes available (Habermacher and Lehmann, 2020). The control of discretion is not simply compressing the administrative discretion space as small as possible (Petersen et al., 2020). Environmental problems in China are particularly complex (Chen et al., 2019). SDEAP is a slight change in environmental policy but affects the whole situation. Government, firms, and households are all involved in it. For example, environmental penalties positively affect firms’ emission reduction (He et al., 2022). Investors are sensitive to environmental penalties for firms (Wu et al., 2022). It will increase equity costs (Ding & Shahzad, 2022) and audit fees (Xin et al., 2022). That’s to say, environmental penalties under SDEAP affect the firms’ and households’ behavior. It is a multi-agent system with a knock-on effect. It is not easy to get a conclusion consistent with reality only by discussing it from a theoretical perspective.
Given the controversy between policymakers and scholars, examining the effect of SDEAP has become a real problem for us. This study constructs a multi-agent dynamic game model, including government, firms, and households. The main contributions of this study are as follows.
1) This study solves the controversy between policymakers and scholars. There is a vague understanding of whether SDEAP helps or hinders enforcement. In this study, a multi-agent dynamic game model is constructed and simulated. The parameters in the model are estimated by the statistical data of China from 2000 to 2020. The result is persuasive for policymakers and scholars.
2) This study draws out three key elements of SDEAP. How to incorporate SDEAP into the game model is a complex problem. Few studies focus on the specific model construction of the SDEAP. This study divides SDEAP into three parts: the intensity of standardized discretion and the lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount. This study is an exploration from practice to the theoretical model. It is meaningful for further model construction.
3) The study conducts a multi-agent dynamic game model to assess the effect of SDEAP. Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium is applied in it. It is a methodological improvement. By solving the dynamic equilibria, we clarify the multi-agent mechanism under SDEAP. It reveals how the government, firms, and households interact. By some numerical simulations, the effects of three key elements are apparent. We put forward policy implications accordingly. It is valuable for improving environmental policy in the future.
2 Literature review
2.1 Discretion and standardized discretion of environmental administrative penalty
Since Hart proposed discretion in the mid-20th century (Hart, 1997), the debate over discretion has been protracted. The school represented by De Montesquieu (2003) advocated denying and eliminating discretion. The school represented by Frank and Bix (2017) advocated the individual initiative factor in law enforcement discretion. For all that, discretion is still applied in the legal system and evolved into two forms: judicial discretion and administrative discretion. This study reviews the literature along the research field of administrative discretion in environmental penalty.
2.1.1 Discretion of environmental administrative penalty
Discretion is unavoidable in an environmental administrative penalty (Zhang et al., 2018). Some scholars have theoretically discussed discretion. Arabadjieva (2017) believed that administrative discretion leaves space to respond to variable pollution behaviors. However, some scholars hold different views. Zhang et al.(2018) thought that discretionary power is executed differently and leads to different results, which is often controversial (Rivera & Knox, 2022). The penalty amount depends on the direction of the EPB’s environmental preferences (Fang et al., 2020). The EPB pays more attention to environmental protection than economic development. The above disputes also exist in empirical studies. He et al. (2022) found an environmental deterrent effect of environmental penalties. It can encourage deterrence and improve compliance by making penalties less predictable for firms (Germani et al., 2017). There are also opposing views. Gong et al. (2019) revealed the presence of a high level of discretion and considerable inconsistency in court judgments. Kang and Silveria (2021) found heterogeneity in penalties for observably similar violations. These studies show that discretion in environmental protection may not be appropriately applied. The root of the dispute lies in the broad range of discretion.
More than that, other scholars found government firms collusion (Hu & Shi, 2021), administrative corruption (Hao et al., 2022), and other problems that lead to apparent unfairness of administrative behavior (Catalano & Pezzolla, 2017; Yamazaki & Takeda, 2017). It is inconsistent with China’s high-quality development goal of both eco-environment and economic development (Jiang et al., 2022; Yuan et al., 2022).
2.1.2 Standardized discretion of environmental administrative penalty
Many scholars put forward the defect of discretion, but only a few suggested how to improve it. Duflo et al.(2018) believed regulatory discretion is extensively valued for administrative supervision. Zhu et al. (2022) thought that discretion raises concerns about weak environmental enforcement. The central government must regulate local administrative discretion. Tadaki (2020) proposed that it is necessary to reveal frontiers for formulating and engaging in discretion. This method of limiting frontiers is consistent with SDEAP. Hu and Zhu (2021) constructed an environmental penalty strategy. In this strategy, environmental protection administrative departments can use their discretion within a specific range. These studies are explorations of standardized discretion in theoretical construction.
Studies on discretion and standardized discretion are shown in Table 4. It lacks assessment for SDEAP. SDEAP has been implemented in China for several years. How effective is SDEAP? There is no conclusion so far. This study constructs a multi-agent dynamic game model to make up study gaps in the SDEAP assessment.
2.2 Multi-agent game of environmental administrative penalty
To explore the effect of environmental administrative penalties, scholars constructed game models between the government and the firm (Cai et al., 2016; Wang and Shi, 2019; He et al., 2022; Peng et al., 2022). Scholars found that the agents in the game models are multiple. Duan et al. (2016) emphasized the importance of the overall interests of society and constructed a multi-agent game model including government, firms, and social interests. Chen et al. (2019) considered consumers’ supervision and analyzed the interaction among firms, governments, and the public. Jiang et al. (2019) believed that central government planners are essential. They constructed an asymmetric dynamic game model of the polluting firms, local government, and central government planners to explore the implementation process of multi-agent environmental regulation strategies. Xu et al. (2019) believed environmental services companies are essential. They built a multi-agent game model, including governments, environmental services companies, and firms. Su (2020) created a multi-agent game model among the government, waste producer, and waste recycler to study the role of government supervision. Shan et al. (2021) considered the surrounding residents’ behaviors and built a multi-agent game model among the government, firms, and surrounding residents. Zou et al. (2022) considered consumers’ willingness to buy low-carbon products and built a ‘government-firm-public’ multi-agent game model. Studies are shown in Table 5.
The above studies have two weaknesses. Firstly, the environmental administrative penalty is simplified to a fixed amount. It is inconsistent with the actual situation in China. Like the example of Heze City, there are different penalties for environmental violations. In addition, households’ behavior is often set as exogenous variables. However, it has been confirmed households’ behavior would be affected by environmental administrative penalties (Wu et al., 2022). And it will affect firms’ costs (Ding & Shahzad, 2022). To assess the SDEAP policy effectiveness, this study improves the model by dynamic stochastic general equilibrium.
2.3 Summary
As a powerful tool for environmental protection, an environmental administrative penalty has attracted extensive academic attention. The dispute has never stopped, whether it is about discretion or standardized discretion. From the perspective of study contents, variable theoretical constructions and policy assessments about the discretion of environmental administrative penalty are carried out. Scholars have been skeptical of environmental administrative discretion. It indicates that SDEAP is meaningful. However, the study on SDEAP, a new, widely practiced tool in China, is not enough. Only a few scholars studied it, and it lacks SDEAP assessment. Therefore, our study has theoretical significance. From the perspective of study methods, multi-agent game models under different environmental means were built. It provides us with a method for solving the problem. However, simplifying some variables cannot truly reflect the strength and impact of the environmental administrative penalty.
This study constructs a “government-firms-households” multi-agent game model to fill the gap. To improve the study methods, we adopt dynamic stochastic general equilibrium theory referring to Evstigneev et al. (2020). By seeking dynamic equilibrium equations and simulating the policy effect, we try to find the mechanism of SDEAP’s impact on the eco-environment and economy.
3 The model
SDEAP has three essential elements: the intensity of standardized discretion and the lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount. It refines the discretion employing “Discretion Table + Formula”. It can restrict the government’s discretion and enable the firms to understand the consequences of pollutant emissions.
The operation mechanism is shown in Figure 1. i) For the households, they provide capital and labor for the firms. The households consume the products the firms produce and are affected by the quality of the eco-environment. ii) For the firms, they produce products by renting capital and labor. It also generates and discharges pollutants to the environmental sector, which the government penalizes. The firms will maximize their profits by coordinating output and emission reduction efforts. iii) The government puts fines according to SDEAP and enhances SDEAP construction, which can restrict firms’ pollutant discharge behavior. The environmental sector is affected by the pollutants discharged. The eco-environment quality has an impact on households.
3.1 Model construction
According to Figure 1, the multi-agent model is constructed as follows.
3.1.1 Households
In the model, the households are homogeneous. Each has the same preference and can survive indefinitely. The households’ utility is affected by consumption, labor, and eco-environment quality (Gao & Xin, 2022). The utility function is the Coefficient of Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA). It is given by
where
where
where
3.1.2 Firms
We use the Cobb-Douglas function for the firm’s production function as follows:
where
where
The pollutant emission
where
where
where
The refinement level
where
where
The level of pollutant emissions
where
The firms maximize their profits by adjusting production and emission reduction. The firm’s profit is given by
where
3.1.3 Government
The government gets revenue by collecting environmental penalties and then puts it under standardized discretion. The constraint function is given by
3.2 Model solution
To fully consider the impact of eco-environment quality on households, firms, and government, we assume that.
1) The eco-environment quality is a dynamic evolution process with self-purification ability.
where
2) The market-clearing state of production is given by
3) The market-clearing state of labor is given by
4) The market-clearing state of capital is given by
The model is solved by the Lagrange multiplier method. The evolutionary equilibrium solution of this multi-agent dynamic game model meets the following equations.
1) The relationship between wage rate, consumption, and labor supply is expressed as
2) The relationship between consumption change rate and return on capital is expressed as
3) The relationship between capital, return on capital, output, lower limit, upper limit, refinement level of SDEAP, and emission reduction efforts are expressed as
4) The relationship between labor supply, wage rate, output, lower limit, upper limit, refinement level of SDEAP, and emission reduction efforts is expressed as
5) The relationship between emission reduction efforts, output, lower limit, upper limit, and refinement level of SDEAP is expressed as
4 Parameters calibration and estimation
The above solutions are implicit. Therefore, we need to calibrate and estimate the parameters. The parameter values such as
4.1 Parameters calibration
Regarding the existing studies, we calibrate the parameters. The results are shown in Table 6.
4.2 Parameters estimation
We set
5 Dynamic effect and conduction mechanism
After estimating parameters, the dynamic numerical simulations of SDEAP are carried out. We analyze the impulse responses of the intensity of standardized discretion and the lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount.
5.1 Dynamic effect analysis of intensity of standardized discretion
The dynamic effect of the intensity of standardized discretion is shown in Figure 3. i) For the government, the balance between eco-environment protection and economic development matters. The intensity of standardized discretion shock has a positive effect on output but a negative effect on eco-environment quality in the short term. In the long term, the negative effect on the eco-environment quality will gradually decrease and close to zero. ii) For the firms, a fair business environment under standardized discretion promotes firms to increase output. So, the capital increases, and labor demand increases first and then decreases. At the same time, the wage increases, and the return on capital increases first and then decreases. Firms will improve their emission reduction efforts. However, the pollution reduction due to emission reduction efforts is less than the pollution generated by output. Therefore, pollutant emissions will still increase in the first three periods. iii) For the households, total incomes increase with labor supply and capital investment. The increased income is partly used for capital investment and partly for consumption.
In the short term, standardized discretion increases output but decreases eco-environment quality. It is explained as follows. A fair business environment is created for firms under standardized discretion. A suitable business environment helps promote the output of firms (Qi et al., 2022). Pollutants will inevitably be generated in the production process (Grossman and Krueger, 1992). As Germani et al. (2017) proposed, standardized discretion reduces the unpredictability of the penalty amount. The deterrent effect is weakened (He et al., 2022), causing firms may not to make efforts to reduce emissions. Due to insufficient emission reduction efforts, production will inevitably lead to pollutant emissions. Under this condition, the pollutant emissions exceed the self-purification ability of the eco-environment. Therefore, the increase in output in the short term leads to the rise of pollutant emissions. The negative effect on the eco-environment quality is evident at the beginning. In a short period, The effect is not very ideal. The result is different from that of Duflo et al.(2018), Tadaki (2020), Kang and Silveria (2021), etc.
In the long term, it is consistent with the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC). As the effect on output gradually weakens, pollutant emissions will no longer increase. In addition, the eco-environment has a self-purification ability. The negative impact on the eco-environment will eventually be eliminated. Since China’s development stage is still on the left side of EKC, the eco-environment has slightly deteriorated with the economic growth. After reaching the ‘inflection point’, the eco-environment will be significantly improved.
5.2 Dynamic effect analysis of lower limit of administrative penalty amount
The dynamic effect of the lower limit is shown in Figure 4. i) For the government, the lower limit has a positive impact on eco-environment quality but a negative effect on the output. This negative effect gradually disappears in the third period. ii) For the firms, the output will be reduced so as not to touch the lower limit of punishment. So, the capital decreases, and labor demand decreases first and then increases. At the same time, the wage decreases, and the return on capital decreases first and then increases. Although firms reduce their emission reduction efforts, pollutant emissions still decrease due to the reduction of output. iii) For the households, total incomes decrease with the decreases in labor supply and capital investment. The consumption also decreases.
In the short term, setting the lower limit increases eco-environment quality but decreases output. It is explained as follows. The lower limit sets the minimum violation cost. The penalty amount is lower than the cost of clean technology innovation. Firms have no motivation to carry out cleaner production. However, pollution emissions without cleaner production will exceed the standard and result in penalties. Firms would reduce output to reduce pollutant emissions to avoid the lower limit. Furtherly, emission reduction efforts are meaningless when the emissions are below the lower limit. Firms want to minimize emission reduction efforts and decrease costs to maximize profits.
In the long term, the output reduction will gradually disappear because the firms will find the most considerable output under the constraint of the lower limit. A balance will be formed in the long term.
5.3 Dynamic effect analysis of upper limit of administrative penalty amount
The dynamic effect of the upper limit is shown in Figure 5. i) The upper limit positively affects eco-environment quality and output for the government. It balances eco-environment protection and economic development. ii) For the firms, they increase output and emission reduction efforts. So, the capital increases, and labor demand increases first and then decreases. At the same time, the wage increases, and the return on capital increases first and then falls. Under the upper limit, the pollutant reduction due to emission reduction efforts is more than the pollutant generated by output. Therefore, the pollutant emission is reduced. iii) For the households, total incomes increase with labor supply and capital investment. The increased income is partly used for capital investment and partly for consumption.
In the short term, the upper limit will promote output and emission reduction efforts at the same time. The result coincides with Cai et al. (2016). A high penalty amount has a deterrent effect. It is unrealistic to reduce pollution emissions simply by reducing output. High penalty amounts can force firms to reduce emissions by promoting clean energy and increasing pollution control equipment and product process innovation (Bu & Shi, 2021). These are firms’ emission reduction efforts. Then the pollutant emission will be greatly reduced. Under the eco-environmental self-purification ability, eco-environmental quality is improved significantly in the short term. Therefore, it can reduce pollutant emissions, improve the eco-environment quality, and achieve dual benefits for the eco-environment and economy.
In the long term, the positive effect on output gradually decreases, while the positive impact on the eco-environment lasts. It is because the use of clean energy, pollution control equipment, and product process innovation could reduce pollutant emissions for a long time.
5.4 Sensitivity analysis
This chapter examines the robustness of the model. We selected three key variables: output, eco-environment quality, and pollutant emissions. The dynamic effects are shown in Figure 6 when the shocks fluctuate up and down by 15%. In Figure 6, lines 1–3 respectively correspond to the impact of a 15% fluctuation in the intensity of standardized discretion, the lower limit, and the upper limit. We find that when each shock fluctuates up and down by 15%, the effect directions do not change. The selection of the initial value of external impact does not vary the overall change trend of variables. The research conclusion has high reliability.
6 Conclusion and implications
6.1 Conclusion
From the legal rules and enforcement process, we draw out three key elements of SDEAP: the intensity of standardized discretion and the lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount. By constructing a multi-agent dynamic game model, we studied the dynamic effect of SDEAP on the economy and eco-environment. The results show that i) The intensity of standardized discretion will promote output growth and improve emission reduction efforts. But it has a specific adverse effect on eco-environmental quality. This negative effect is mainly because the emission reduction efforts of firms are lower than the output increase. The negative effect on eco-environmental quality will gradually disappear in the long run. ii) The lower limit will simultaneously reduce output and emission reduction efforts. The output decline will reduce pollutant emissions and positively affect the eco-environment. It is not conducive to economic development in the short term. The negative effect on economic development will gradually disappear in the long run. iii) The upper limit has a positive effect on the eco-environment and output simultaneously. It is conducive to the joint development of the economy and eco-environment.
6.2 Policy implications
Overall, SDEAP restricts the broad range of discretion. It can promote economic growth, but discretion should not be excessively squeezed. In the short term, SDEAP cannot achieve the high-quality development goal of the joint development of the economy and eco-environment. In a long time, it can balance eco-environment quality and economic development. The following policy implications are put forward.
1) As a new constraint method, there are still many problems in SDEAP. In the current SDEAP construction, more attention is paid to standardized discretion. The other two key elements (lower and upper limits) are not concerned they deserved. The lower and upper limits of the administrative penalty amount need to be adjusted in time with the economic development. Especially the upper limit, it can achieve the dual goals of eco-environment protection and economic development. It plays an essential role in harmonizing eco-environment protection and economic development.
2) It is a long way to achieve the high-quality development goal of the joint development of the economy and eco-environment. At the initial stage of policy adjustment, it may be impossible to consider eco-environment protection and economic development. In an extended period, the high-quality development goal can be achieved. Therefore, we should look at short-term and long-term effects.
6.3 Limitations and further researchs
This study contends with several limitations. To highlight the effect of SDEAP, we simplified governments into one department. In reality, governments in China are divided into central and local governments. They have different government powers. For example, the Central Regulations on Supervision of Ecological Environment Protection was issued in 2019. The central government supervises local governments. Future works could study the role of central government supervision in SDEAP. Besides, environmental non-governmental organizations (ENGOs) are critical social forces. ENGOs are effective bridges connecting the government, firms, and households. Future work could take ENGO as a player in the multi-agent game model.
Data availability statement
The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.
Author contributions
XM: Methodology, Formal analysis, Software, Data processing, Writing-original draft, Investigation. BX: Conceptualisation, Methodology, Investigation, Writing-review and editing, Supervision, Validation, Resources. GW: Conceptualisation, Investigation, Validation.
Funding
This work was supported by the National Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Science of China (Grant No. 21BJY206), and Social Science Planning Project of Shandong Province (Grant No. 19BJCJ67).
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.
Publisher’s note
All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.
Footnotes
1The administrative penalties in Table 1 were made according to the law of 2000. Now the law was supplemented and revised in 2015.
2Data is obtained from the Ecological Environment Bureau of Heze city: http://hzsthj.heze.gov.cn/col/col66818/index.html?uid=88124&pageNum=48.
3The administrative penalties in Table 2 were made according to the law of 1997. Now the law was supplemented and revised in 2022.
4Data is obtained from Weihai Ecological Environment Bureau: http://sthjj.weihai.gov.cn/col/col81006/index.html?uid=207606&pageNum=52.
5Article 48 is shown as an example in Heze City. This article was not changed in 2015.
6It is from the Catalogue of Administrative Penalty of Environmental Protection Administration Set by Laws.
730 May 2019. The Relevant Person in Charge of the Ministry of Ecological and Environment Answered the Reporter’s Questions on the Guiding Opinions on Further Standardizing the Discretion of Environmental Administrative Penalty.
822 May 2019. The Ministry of Ecology and Environment issued One of the Bases of Guiding Opinion on Further Standardizing the Discretion of Environmental Administrative Penalty Is the Notice of the General Office of the State Council on Focusing on the Concerns of Enterprises and Further Promoting the Implementation of Policies to Optimize the Business Environment.
References
Angelopoulos, K., Economides, G., and Philippopoulos, A. (2010). DEOS working papers No.2980. What is the best environmental policy? Taxes, permits and rules under economic and environmental uncertainty. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1571058
Arabadjieva, K. (2017). Vagueness and discretion in the scope of the EIA directive. J. Environ. Law 29 (3), 417–444. doi:10.1093/jel/eqx011
Bu, C., and Shi, D. (2021). The emission reduction effect of daily penalty policy on firms. J. Environ. Manage. 294, 112922. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.112922
Cai, L., Cai, W., Zhu, C., Chen, S., and Mengting, Z. (2016). An optimal penalty in an environmental pollution game with the suspension of production. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 31 (4), 2321–2333. doi:10.3233/JIFS-169073
Catalano, M., and Pezzolla, E. (2017). The Italian labor market reform: An evaluation of the jobs act using the prometeia DSGE model. Ital. Econ. J. 3, 209–238. doi:10.1007/s40797-017-0057-z
Chang, L., Song, Y. D., and Yu, T. (2020). Optimization of financial penalties for environmental pollution by Chinese traditional energy enterprises. Front. Environ. Sci. 11, 610152. doi:10.3389/fenvs.2020.610152
Chen, Y. X., Zhang, J., Tadikamalla, P. R., and Gao, X. T. (2019). The Relationship among government, enterprise, and public in environmental governance from the perspective of multi-player evolutionary game. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 16 (18), 3351. doi:10.3390/ijerph16183351
De Montesquieu, C. (2013). Montesquieu: The spirit of the laws. New York, NY, USA: Cambridge University Press. Book 12.
Ding, X. A., and Shahzad, M. (2022). Effect of environmental penalties on the cost of equity-The role of corporate environmental disclosures. Pol. J. Environ. Stud. 31 (2), 1073–1082. doi:10.15244/pjoes/141807
Duan, W., Li, C., Zhang, P., and Chang, Q. (2016). Game modeling and policy research on the system dynamics-based tripartite evolution for government environmental regulation. Clust. Comput. 19 (4), 2061–2074. doi:10.1007/s10586-016-0642-1
Duflo, E., Greenstone, M., Pande, R., and Ryan, N. (2018). The value of regulatory discretion: Estimates from environmental inspections in India. Econometrica 86 (6), 2123–2160. doi:10.3982/ecta12876
Evstigneev, I., Hens, T., Potapova, V., and Schenk-Hoppé, K. R. (2020). Behavioral equilibrium and evolutionary dynamics in asset markets. J. Math. Econ. 91, 121–135. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2020.09.004
Fang, D. B., Wang, D., and Kleit, A. N. (2020). How a choice between emission trading and tax schemes affects an environment-biased Environmental Protection Bureau's discretion? Sci. Total Environ. 736, 139141. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.139141
Gao, F. F., and Xin, B. G. (2022). Effects of eco-environmental damage compensation system with multi-stakeholder engagements: A DSGE perspective from China. Environ. Res. Commun. 4, 015001. doi:10.1088/2515-7620/ac4877
Germani, A. R., Scaramozzino, P., Morone, A., and Morone, P. (2017). Discretionary enforcement and strategic interactions between enforcement agencies and firms: A theoretical and laboratory investigation. J. Regul. Econ. 52 (3), 255–284. doi:10.1007/s11149-017-9341-y
Gong, T., Wang, S. R., and Li, H. (2019). Sentencing disparities in corruption cases in China. J. Contemp. China 28 (116), 245–259. doi:10.1080/10670564.2018.1511395
Grossman, G., and Krueger, A. B. (1992). Environmental impacts of a North American free trade agreement. C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers 644. Available at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/cpr/ceprdp/644.html.
Habermacher, F., and Lehmann, P. (2020). Commitment versus discretion in climate and energy policy. Environ. Resour. Econ. (Dordr). 76 (1), 39–67. doi:10.1007/s10640-020-00414-3
Hao, Y., Xu, L., Guo, Y. X., and Wu, H. T. (2022). The inducing factors of environmental emergencies: Do environmental decentralization and regional corruption matter? J. Environ. Manage. 302, 114098. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.114098
He, L., Zhong, T. Y., Gan, S. D., Liu, J. M., and Xu, C. Y. (2022). Penalties vs. Subsidies: A study on which is better to promote corporate environmental governance. Front. Environ. Sci. 10, 859591. doi:10.3389/fenvs.2022.859591
Hu, C. Y., and Zhu, S. H. (2021). Method of setting environmental administrative fine amounts. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 18 (9), 5011. doi:10.3390/ijerph18095011
Hu, K., and Shi, D. Q. (2021). The impact of government-enterprise collusion on environmental pollution in China. J. Environ. Manage. 292, 112744. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.112744
Jiang, K., You, D., Merrill, R., and Li, Z. (2019). Implementation of a multi-agent environmental regulation strategy under Chinese fiscal decentralization: An evolutionary game theoretical approach. J. Clean. Prod. 214, 902–915. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.12.252
Jiang, T. Y., Yu, Y., Jahanger, A., and Balsalobre-Lorente, D. (2022). Structural emissions reduction of China's power and heating industry under the goal of “double carbon”: A perspective from input-output analysis. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 31, 346–356. doi:10.1016/j.spc.2022.03.003
Kang, K., and Silveira, B. (2021). Understanding disparities in punishment: Regulator preferences and expertise. J. Polit. Econ. 129 (10), 2947–2992. doi:10.1086/715415
Kochtcheeva, L. V. (2010). Administrative discretion and environmental regulation: Agency substantive rules and court decisions in U.S. air and water quality policies. Rev. Policy Res. 26 (3), 241–265. doi:10.1111/j.1541-1338.2009.00381.x
Kong, Y., He, W., Yuan, L., Zhang, Z., Gao, X., Degefu, D. M., et al. (2021). Decoupling economic growth from water consumption in the yangtze river economic belt, China. Ecol. Indic. 123, 107344. doi:10.1016/j.ecolind.2021.107344
Konstant, A. (2016). Rights, administrative discretion and Dawood. S. Afr. J. Hum. Rights 32 (1), 106–129. doi:10.1080/02587203.2016.1162441
Li, B., and Liu, Q. (2017). On the choice of monetary policy rules for China: A bayesian dsge approach. China Econ. Rev. 44, 166–185. doi:10.1016/j.chieco.2017.04.004
Liu, L., and He, L. Y. (2021). Output and welfare effect of green credit in China: Evidence from an estimated DSGE model. J. Clean. Prod. 294, 126326. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126326
Ma, D. L., Xiong, H. T., Zhang, F. T., Gao, L., Zhao, N., Yang, G. M., et al. (2022). China’s industrial green total-factor energy efficiency and its influencing factors: A spatial econometric analysis. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 29, 18559–18577. doi:10.1007/s11356-021-17040-1
Peng, W., Xin, B. G., and Xie, L. (2022). Optimal strategies for product price, customer environmental volunteering, and corporate environmental responsibility. J. Clean. Prod. 364, 132635. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.132635
Petersen, A., Christensen, L. R., and Hildebrandt, T. T. (2020). The Role of discretion in the age of automation. Comput. Support. Coop. Work 29 (1), 303–333. doi:10.1007/s10606-020-09371-3
Qi, Y., Shao, S., Tian, Z., Xu, Y., and Yin, J. (2022). Environmental consequences of fair competition: Evidence from China's corporate income tax merger policy. Ecol. Econ. 195, 107365. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2022.107365
Rivera, J. D., and Knox, C. C. (2022). Bureaucratic discretion, social equity, and the administrative legitimacy dilemma. Complications of new public service. Public Adm. Rev., 1–13. doi:10.1111/puar.13550
Sancho, F. (2021). The mitigation potential of eco-taxation on carbon emissions: Income effects under downward rigid wages. Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 23, 93–107. doi:10.1007/s10018-020-00280-9
Shan, S. N., Duan, X., Ji, W. Y., Zhang, T. T., and Li, H. (2021). Evolutionary game analysis of stakeholder behavior strategies in 'Not in My Backyard' conflicts: Effect of the intervention by environmental non-governmental organizations. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 28, 829–847. doi:10.1016/j.spc.2021.07.012
Smets, F., and Wouters, R. (2004). Shocks and frictions in U.S. Business cycles: A bayesian dsge approach. SSRN J. 97 (3), 586–606. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1687574
Su, Y. B. (2020). Multi-agent evolutionary game in the recycling utilization of construction waste. Sci. Total Environ. 738, 139826. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.139826
Tadaki, M. (2020). Is there space for politics in the environmental bureaucracy? Discretion and constraint in aotearoa New Zealand's Ministry for the environment. Geoforum 111, 229–238. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2020.02.021
Tu, Q. Y., and Wang, Y. (2022). Analysis of the synergistic effect of carbon taxes and clean energy subsidies: An enterprise-heterogeneity E-DSGE model approach. Clim. Chang. Econ. (Singap). 13, 01. doi:10.1142/S2010007822400127
Wang, Q., and Wang, S. (2022). The impact of environmental regulation on water resources utilization efficiency. Front. Environ. Sci. 10, 1022929. doi:10.3389/fenvs.2022.1022929
Wang, S. H., Wang, X. Q., and Lu, B. B. (2022). Is resource abundance a curse for green economic growth? Evidence from developing countries. Resour. Policy 75, 102533. doi:10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102533
Wang, S., and Shi, F. (2019). An evolutionary game model for industrial pollution management under two punishment mechanisms. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 16 (15), 2775. doi:10.3390/ijerph16152775
Wu, H., Feng, T. W., Jiang, W. B., and Kong, T. (2022). Environmental penalties, investor attention and stock market reaction: Moderating roles of air pollution and industry saliency. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 19 (5), 2660. doi:10.3390/ijerph19052660
Xin, C. H., Hao, X. L., and Cheng, L. (2022). Do environmental administrative penalties affect audit fees? Results from multiple econometric models. Sustainability 14 (7), 4268. doi:10.3390/su14074268
Xu, R., Wang, Y. R., Wang, W. B., and Ding, Y. X. (2019). Evolutionary game analysis for third-party governance of environmental pollution. J. Ambient. Intell. Humaniz. Comput. 10 (8), 3143–3154. doi:10.1007/s12652-018-1034-6
Yamazaki, M., and Takeda, S. (2017). A computable general equilibrium assessment of Japan’s nuclear energy policy and implications for renewable energy. Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 19, 537–554. doi:10.1007/s10018-016-0164-3
Yu, Y., Jiang, T., Li, S., Li, X., and Gao, D. (2020). Energy-related CO2 emissions and structural emissions’ reduction in China’s agriculture: An input–output perspective. J. Clean. Prod. 276, 124169. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124169
Yuan, L., Li, R. Y., He, W. J., Wu, X., Kong, Y., Degefu, D. M., et al. (2022). Coordination of the industrial-ecological economy in the yangtze river economic belt, China. Front. Environ. Sci. 10, 882221. doi:10.3389/fenvs.2022.882221
Zhang, J., Kornov, L., and Christensen, P. (2018). The discretionary power of the environmental assessment practitioner. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 72 (9), 25–32. doi:10.1016/j.eiar.2018.04.008
Zhang, W. (2009). China’s monetary policy: Quantity versus price rules. J. Macroecon. 31 (3), 473–484. doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2008.09.003
Zhao, W., Lu, Y., Zhao, M. J., and Zhang, P. (2020). Fluctuations in the open economy of China: Evidence from the ABNK model. Emerg. Mark. Finance Trade 56 (9), 2073–2092. doi:10.1080/1540496X.2019.1635451
Zhu, X., Ding, L., Li, H. Y., and Gong, Y. Z. (2022). A new national environmental law with harsh penalties and regulated discretion: Experiences and lessons from China. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 181, 106245. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2022.106245
Keywords: multi-agent game, standardized discretion, environmental administrative penalty, dynamic equilibrium, green development
Citation: Ma X, Xin B and Wu G (2023) Multi-agent game analysis on standardized discretion of environmental administrative penalty. Front. Environ. Sci. 10:1064333. doi: 10.3389/fenvs.2022.1064333
Received: 08 October 2022; Accepted: 05 December 2022;
Published: 05 January 2023.
Edited by:
Fengtai Zhang, Chongqing University of Technology, ChinaCopyright © 2023 Ma, Xin and Wu. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.
*Correspondence: Baogui Xin, xin@sdust.edu.cn
†ORCID: Baogui Xin, orcid.org/0000-0002-7739-4808