Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Energy Res., 28 July 2023
Sec. Smart Grids

Response capability evaluation model of electric vehicle aggregator based on evolutionary game and response anticipation

Updated
Xiangchu Xu
Xiangchu Xu1*Zengqiang MiZengqiang Mi1Zewei ZhanZewei Zhan1Ling JiLing Ji2
  • 1State Key Laboratory of Alternate Electrical Power System with Renewable Energy Sources, North China Electric Power University, Baoding, China
  • 2Nanjing SAC Power Grid Automation Co., Ltd., Nanjing, China

Accurately quantitative evaluation of the response capability of electric vehicle aggregator (EVA), i.e., the adjustable range of power, is the premise and basis of its participation in the demand response (DR). In response to the current EVA’s response capability evaluation, ignoring the autonomy of EV decision-making behavior may lead to overly idealized evaluation results, as well as the problem of evaluating only from a single time scale. To this end, this paper proposes a response capability evaluation model of EVA based on evolutionary game and response anticipation. Based on the physical constraints of EVs and their willingness to discharge, response capability evaluation models are constructed for individual EVs of different response types. Considering the autonomy of decision-making behavior of EVs, an evolutionary game model with multi-strategy sets of EVs is constructed. Based on the idea of response anticipation, a regulation strategy is proposed for EVA to achieve the dynamic update of EVA’s response capability. The proposed model is verified to be able to accurately evaluate the EVA’s response capability through simulation examples, and the EVA response capability evaluation is extended from a single time scale to multiple time scales. The evaluation results can be used as the basis for EVA to participate in the electricity market bidding.

1 Introduction

Due to the advantages of energy saving and zero emission, the market share of EVs is growing rapidly with the support of relevant policies. According to the Global EV Outlook 2021 report published by the International Energy Agency, the number of EVs worldwide has reached about 10 million in 2020 and is expected to soar to 145 million by 2030 (IEA, 2021). In addition, demand response (DR) has received increasing attention from researchers as a means of using customer-side resources to relieve pressure on the system supply-demand balance (Shariatzadeh et al., 2015). Therefore, EVs are a highly promising resource for flexible regulation to be exploited.

However, the capacity of an individual EV is small and decentralized in the system, which cannot be directly deployed by the system (Xu et al., 2023). EVA, as an emerging market entity between the electricity market and EVs, can integrate EVs in a region into an aggregator with large adjustable capacity and simplicity control. With the development of artificial intelligence (Cheng and Yu, 2019a) and energy internet (Cheng and Yu, 2019b), EVA can respond to system dispatch or participate in the electricity market, while providing a variety of ancillary services to the system, such as peak shaving and valley filling, frequency regulation, spinning reserve (Han et al., 2019). There have been many studies related to DR management applications and aggregator participation in electricity markets. A profit-maximization-based pricing optimization model for DR management with customer behavior learning in the context of smart grids was presented (Meng and Zeng, 2016). A game theory-based approach to obtain the optimal bidding strategy for DR aggregators in the electricity market was proposed (Abapour et al., 2019a). A game-theoretic approach to the optimal bidding strategy for DR aggregators in deregulated energy markets was provided (Abapour et al., 2019b). A bilevel game-theoretic model for multiple strategic retailers participating in both wholesale and local electricity markets while considering customers’ switching behaviors was proposed (Hong et al., 2023).

Aggregators need to evaluate their response capability in advance before participating in the electricity market. Response capability of the EVA is the adjustable range of power that can be regulated up (charge or stop discharging) or down (stop charging or discharging) from the baseline power. Accurately quantitative evaluation of EVA’s response capability is the prerequisite basis for its participation in DR. Overestimation of response capability carries the risk of under-response, which may endanger system safety, underestimation of response capability will waste EV’s DR potential and cause economic loss.

A number of studies have been conducted around the response capability evaluation of EVAs. The aggregated response capability of EVs in parking lot charging stations using queuing theory was evaluated (Chukwu and Mahajan, 2014). (Zhang and Kezunovic, 2016) evaluated the response capability of EV clusters based on Markov process. A robust virtual battery model-based method for evaluating the response capability of large-scale plug-in EVs was proposed (Hu et al., 2021). The response capability of a cluster of parked EVs was considered to be proportional to the number of connected EVs (Han et al., 2011). A recursive idea-based model for evaluating the temporal response capability of EV switching station was developed (Liu et al., 2017). (Lam et al., 2016) evaluated the aggregated response capability of EV clusters using a queuing network model. An EV response capability calculation method was proposed to evaluate the response capability of an individual EV and EV clusters under different charging strategies, respectively (Wu et al., 2018). An aggregation model was developed to evaluate the response capability of large-scale plug-in EV clusters (Zhang et al., 2017). (Zhang et al., 2019; Deng et al., 2020) extended the EVA’s response capability evaluation model from a single time scale to multiple time scales. The response capability of EVA in the next time period is dynamically updated according to the response of EVs in the previous time period. The charging-discharging strategies of EVs in the response capability evaluation model constructed in the above literature were entirely determined by the EVA. However, in realistic scenarios, EVA and EV users are different interest entities with different optimization goals in their respective decision-making processes. When evaluating the actual response capability of EVA, ignoring the autonomy of EV decision-making behavior may lead to overly idealized evaluation results.

Under the DR mechanism, the charging-discharging incentive price issued by the EVA to EVs is influenced by the total response volume of the EVs, and the incentive price decreases as the response volume increases. In response to EVA incentives, there is a game relationship between EVs. Each EV is a stakeholder and the economic benefit is influenced by the charging-discharging strategies of other EVs. The traditional game approach makes the dual assumptions of “complete rationality” and “complete information” for the participants, which is obviously not in line with the actual decision-making scenario of EV users, who cannot respond to the information changes quickly and optimally. Therefore, the evolutionary game based on “bounded rationality” and “limited information” can more reasonably characterize the game behavior of EV users in actual decision-making scenarios.

Evolutionary game theory has yielded many achievements in solving power system problems. Based on the framework of evolutionary game theory, an in-depth study of the long-term bidding equilibrium characteristics of homogeneous and heterogeneous power generation-side markets was provided (Cheng et al., 2022). (Cheng et al., 2021) provided an in-depth study of the behavioral decision problem in demand-side response management from the perspective of multiple population evolutionary game dynamics. An evolutionary game model of renewable energy generation and transmission from the perspective of bounded rationality and multi-agents game to analyze the necessity and effectiveness of strengthening relevant government regulation was established (Fang et al., 2018). (Cheng et al., 2020a) focused on the general N-population multi-strategy evolutionary games, and used them to investigate the generation-side long-term bidding issues in electricity market. A hierarchical extension coordinated controller was proposed, which considered the bounded rationality of the control system to address traditional stability control interference on driving speed and driver operation (Zheng et al., 2023). Considering the formation mechanism of greenwashing behaviors and collusion in EV certification processes, a tripartite evolutionary game model based on strategic interactions among manufacturers, certification authorities, and governments was constructed (Liu et al., 2023).

However, there are few studies in the existing literature that use evolutionary game theory to analyze the decision behavior of EV users in real-world scenarios and evaluate response capability of EVA on this basis (Cai et al., 2023). Evaluated the response capability of EVA based on a multi-strategy set evolutionary game model for EVs. The response behavior of EV users to incentives was analyzed using evolutionary game theory, and a method to evaluate response capability of EVs in grid emergencies was proposed (Wu et al., 2021). However, the differential response capability of different types of EVs was not considered and the response capability of EVs was only evaluated from a single time scale, ignoring the impact of EVs responding to system dispatch commands on response capability.

To address the shortcomings of existing studies, this paper proposes a response capability evaluation model of EVA based on evolutionary game and response anticipation, with the following main contributions. 1) EVs are subdivided into inelastic EVs, unidirectional EVs and bidirectional EVs according to the physical constraints of EVs and whether they have the willingness to discharge. Considering the differential response capability of different types of EVs, the response capability evaluation methods of different types of EVs are given. 2) EV users, as highly autonomous individuals, can adjust their charging-discharging strategies according to their own economic benefits. An evolutionary game model with multi-strategy sets of EVs is constructed based on which the response capability of EVs is evaluated. 3) Based on the idea of response anticipation, the influence of EVA response system scheduling instructions on response capability is considered. The response capability evaluation model of EVA is extended from a single time scale to multiple time scales to realize the response capability dynamic update of EVA.

The rest of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the framework for EVA to participate in the electricity market. The methodology for evaluating the response capability of different response types of EVs is given in Section 3. The evolutionary game model is developed in Section 4. Section 5 proposes a multi-time scale response capability evaluation method for EVA. Case studies are conducted in Section 6. Section 7 highlights the conclusions and future work.

2 Electricity market framework

The framework for EVA to participate in the electricity market as an emerging market entity between the ISO and EVs is shown in Figure 1. EVA collects EV information and issues control instructions through smart charging piles, issues charging-discharging incentive prices for the DR period according to the scheduling instruction, and evaluates the aggregated response capability of EVs during the DR period. EVA bids in the electricity market with other interest entities based on the response capability evaluation results. ISO is responsible for the operation and clearing settlement of the electricity market, issues DR time periods and scheduling instructions, and declares electricity price intervals. Based on the bidding capacity and offering price of each interest entity, the winning capacity and winning price of each entity are determined with the goal of economic optimality.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. The framework for EVA to participate in the electricity market.

The focus of this paper is how to quantitatively evaluate the response capability of EVA, which is related to the charging-discharging strategies of EVs. EV users have great autonomy, and can be informed of the economic benefits of their participation in DR through smart charging piles or mobile apps, and change the charging-discharging strategies autonomously. However, EV users are a group of limited rationality, their grasp of other EV users’ information and knowledge of the game environment are limited. They tend to estimate the economic benefits under different strategies based on empirical memory, and their decision-making behavior has a certain degree of randomness.

3 Individual EV model

EV users can determine their own charging and discharging modes. The EVs are subdivided into three categories as follows:

1) Inflexible EV: Continuous charging at rated power during parked period still does not achieve the desired energy.

2) Unidirectional EV: The charging power can be adjusted during grid connection period, but it cannot be fed backwards to the EVA, i.e., it cannot be in the state of discharge.

3) Bidirectional EV: The power can be fed back to EVA in the process of grid connection, i.e., the power can flow in both directions, and the charging and discharging power can be flexibly adjusted in the adjustable interval.

The set composed of three types of EVs is denoted as D0, D1, and D2 respectively. In the actual scenario, the EVs are connected to the grid to determine the set they belong to. EV users can determine it independently by interacting with EVA through smart terminals, and EVA applies differentiated billing or incentives for different response types of EV users. In the following, the three types of EVs are modeled separately.

3.1 Inflexible EV

If the EV satisfies the constraints of Eq. 1, the EV belongs to the set D0, at which time the EV is regarded as an inflexible load and does not have response capability, and its power and energy are calculated as Eqs 2, 3.

picηictidtQiSieSis(1)
pit=picηic,ttis,tid0,ttis,tid(2)
eit=QiSis+picηicttis,ttis,tid(3)

3.2 Unidirectional EV

If the EV satisfies the constraints of Eq. 4 and the user selects the unidirectional charging mode, the EV belongs to the set D1 with the constraints of power and energy as in Eqs 58.

picηictidt>QiSieSis(4)
pi+t=picηc,ttis,tid0,ttis,tid(5)
ei+t=mineitΔt+picηicΔt,QiSimax,ttis,tid(6)
eit=eitΔt+pitηicΔt,ttis,tid(7)
0pitpi+t0eitei+t(8)

where eitΔt is the energy of the EV at time tΔt.

3.3 Bidirectional EV

If the EV satisfies the constraints of Eq. 4 and Sis>Simin, the user selects the bidirectional charging-discharging mode, the EV belongs to D2. The constraints in the charging mode are the same as those of the unidirectional EV, i.e., Eqs 5, 6. In the discharging mode, the power and energy of the EV need to satisfy the constraints as Eqs 911.

pit=pid/ηid,ttis,tid0,ttis,tid(9)
eit=max(eitΔtpidΔt/ηid,QiSimin,QiSiepicηictidt),ttis,tid(10)
eit=eitΔt+pitΔt/ηid,ttis,tid(11)

where Simin is the minimum threshold of SOC to prevent the EV from over-discharging. It is worth noting that to ensure that the EV can reach the expected power when off-grid, the minimum power value allowed to be discharged to at time t is QiSiepicηictidt.

The power and energy constraints to be satisfied by the bidirectional EV are as follows:

pitpitpi+teiteitei+t(12)

4 Evolutionary game model

4.1 Evolutionary game modeling

In an open electricity sales market environment, each EV arranges the charging-discharging power for each time period with its own optimization target. The total charging and discharging power of all EVs under EVA’s jurisdiction during the DR time period will directly determine EVA’s bidding power and energy offer in the electricity market, which in turn affects the winning power and winning price, and thus affects the charging-discharging incentive price issued by EVA to EVs. Therefore, how EVs choose their respective charging-discharging strategies can be viewed as a game problem. Classical game theory is based on the following three assumptions: 1) the participants are perfectly rational, 2) the participants have perfect information, 3) the structure and environment of the game are given in advance (Cheng et al., 2020b). The strong assumptions of classical game theory make it difficult to be applied to the actual EV decision-making scenarios, and evolutionary games based on the assumptions of “bounded rationality” and “limited information” can provide better solutions. The “bounded rationality” and “limited information” refer to the fact that EV users have incomplete knowledge and information, and have limited knowledge of other EV users’ decision-making information and game environment, so the decision-making behavior is somewhat random.

The travel characteristics of EVs are highly stochastic, and the travel characteristics of EVs include EV on-grid/off-grid moment, SOC at on-grid/off-grid, and expected SOC at off-grid moment. EVs with the same travel characteristics have the same charging demand, and the charging-discharging strategies will converge under the same incentives. EVs with the same travel characteristics are considered as an EV population, and their internal charging-discharging strategies are selected based on evolutionary games.

In this paper, each EV is abstracted as an EV population with the same appearance characteristics, and its internal evolutionary game process is modeled. N number of strategies are randomly generated by the EV under the constraints, and the strategy set is the set of charging-discharging power vectors for each time period within the scheduling time period. The strategy set generated by the i-th EV population is denoted as φi, and the expression is as follows:

φi=Si1,Sin,,SiNSin=pi,1n,pi,kn,pi,Kn(13)

where Sin is the n-th strategy generated by the i-th EV population. pi,kn is the charging-discharging power of the k-th time period in the n-th strategy, positive value represents EV charging and negative value represents EV discharging.

The optimization objective of each EV is to minimize the total charging cost by participating in DR while satisfying its own travel needs. The optimization objective of an EV can be represented by a payment function that includes the charging cost, the discharge compensation and the additional cost of battery degradation due to participation in DR. The mathematical expression of the payment function is as follows:

Uin=k=1Kpi,knci,kΔT+a100χi,kQiCd(14)
χi,k=maxei,k1ei,k,0(15)

where ci,k is the EV charging-discharging incentive price during k-th period, the price of DR time period is issued by EVA, and the price of non-DR time period is the grid time-of-use price. a is the linear relationship coefficient between battery life and cycle number. Cd is the battery replacement cost. χi,k is the cycle charging-discharging capacity during the k-th time period.

The dispatch of EVs must first meet their charging demand and ensure that the energy of EVs off-grid should reach the expected energy set by users, with the following corresponding constraints:

QiSieQiSidQiSimax(16)

Each EV population has the same constraint to generate the strategy set because of the consistent travel behavior, and N number of strategies are randomly generated under the constraint. Since the EV control strategy in the set D0 is unique, the strategy set is generated only for the EV populations in the set D1 and D2.

4.2 Dynamic evolution equations

In the evolutionary game process, each EV chooses a charging-discharging strategy independently, and the population state indicates the proportion of EVs in the population choosing each strategy. xint denotes the proportion of the number of individuals in the EV population choosing strategy Sin to the total number, and the constraints to be satisfied are as follows:

0xin1n=1Nxin=1(17)

The evolutionary game model transforms the payoff function Uin into an adaptation function fin that represents the distribution of the strategies chosen by individual in the population and the current individual strategy (Weibull, 2015). The mathematical expression is as follows:

fin=xinUin(18)

It is unlikely that the dynamic evolutionary process of EV selection of charging-discharging strategies will be completed in a single pass. When there is an opportunity to modify the strategy, EV will compare the expected return of selecting the current strategy with the expected return of selecting other strategies and will modify the selected strategy with conditional transformation probability ρ (Weibull, 2015). The EV population charging-discharging strategy will be continuously modified to make the adaptation function optimal and finally equilibrated to evolve a stable strategy. The differential equation for the dynamic evolution of EV population state is as follows:

xink=m=1Nximρim,nxinm=1Nρin,m(19)

where ρim,n and ρin,m are the conditional transition probability of EV from strategy m to strategy n and from strategy n to strategy m, respectively, denoting the proportion of EV transitioned from other strategies to strategies n and from strategy n to other strategies, as determined by the revision protocol of the selected strategy.

The corresponding dynamic evolutionary differential equations will differ depending on the form of the chosen revision protocol. Logit protocol is commonly used in evolutionary game model that simulate EV decision because they take into account the individual preferences and bounded rationality of decision makers (Cai et al., 2023). The expression for the conditional probability when using the Logit revision protocol is as follows:

ρim,n=expfinσ1m=1Nexpfimσ1(20)

Bringing Eq. 20 into Eq. 19 gives the dynamic evolution equation of the EV population as

xink=ρim,nxin=expfinσ1m=1Nexpfimσ1xin(21)

The dynamic evolution equation depicts the game process in the actual decision-making scenario of EV users. When xin/k=0, the evolutionary game of strategies chosen by all individuals in the population will reach equilibrium, at which the economic benefit of the EV population is maximized.

4.3 Evolutionarily stable strategy solving

The dynamic evolution equation of Eq. 21 is discretized and the expression is as follows:

xinθ+1=xinθ+λρim,nxinθ(22)

The flow chart of the evolutionarily stable strategy solution is shown in Figure 2.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. The flow chart of the evolutionarily stable strategy solution.

The evolutionarily stable strategy solving steps are as follows:

1) EVA issues the charging-discharging prices for the DR time period.

2) EV population randomly generates N strategies under the constraints

3) EV population randomly generates the initial each strategy selection ratio x0.

4) Calculate the payment function Uin of EV under each strategy according to Eq. 14.

5) Calculate the adaptation function fin of EV under each strategy by Eq. 18.

6) Calculate the conditional transformation probability ρim,n of the selected strategy by Eq. 20.

7) Calculate the EV population state xinθ.

8) Determine whether xin/k=0 is valid. If not, θ=θ+1, repeat Step 5)∼ Step 7), and update the EV population state according to the dynamic evolution Eq. 22.

9) Until xin/k=0, output the evolutionarily stable strategy of the EV population and the evolutionary state of each strategy.

5 Response capability evaluation of EVA

5.1 Response capability of an individual EV

By discretizing the time axis during the DR time period and assuming that the EV power is constant in period ΔT. The upper and lower bounds of the response capability of an individual EV during time period k can be calculated according to Eqs 23, 24.

pi,kmax=minpi,k+,ei,k+1+ei,k/ΔT/ηic(23)
pi,kmin=maxpi,k,ei,k+1ei,k/ΔTηid(24)

where pi,kmax and pi,kmin are the upper and lower bounds of the response capability of the i-th EV during time period k.

Then the equation for the response capability of an individual EV is as follows:

pi,ku=pi,k,iD1pi,kpi,kmin,iD2(25)
pi,kd=pi,kmaxpi,k(26)

where pi,ku and pi,kd are the regulation up capability and regulation down capability of the i-th EV during time period k. pi,k is the operating power of the EV during time period k.

The response capacity of unidirectional/bidirectional EV during grid-connected hours is shown schematically in Figure 3.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. Schematic diagram of EV’s response capability. (A) Unidirectional EV. (B) Bidirectional EV.

5.2 Response capability of EVA

The formula for the response capability before participation in DR obtained by EVA aggregation is as follows:

Pku=iD1pi,ku+iD2pi,ku(27)
Pkd=iD1pi,kd+iD2pi,kd(28)

where Pku and Pkd are the regulation up capability and regulation down capability of EVA during time period k.

EVA issues the DR time window information in advance, and based on the evolutionary game model, when all EVs adopt the evolutionarily stable strategy, the upper and lower spare capacities that EVA can provide under a given DR time window can be evaluated by Eqs 27, 28.

5.3 Dynamic update of EVA’s response capability

EVA participation in DR will cause changes in its own response capability. When EVA responds to the scheduling control command PkS of ISO during time period k, the charging-discharging state and SOC of the controlled EV will change accordingly, which will have an impact on the intra-day response capability of EVA during time period k+1. Therefore, it is necessary to dynamically update the EVA’ response capability to ensure the availability of EVA’ response capability evaluation results during the continuous DR period.

To address this issue, this paper further proposes an evaluation model based on the idea of response anticipation to dynamically evaluate the response capability of EVA. The variation of EVA’s response capability is closely related to its scheduling strategy. In this paper, we propose a regulation strategy considering RTM and SOC indexes. The priority queue is generated by combining the RTM and SOC of each EV, and the response is obtained by taking into account the scheduling instruction and user travel demand on the basis of merit participation, and finally the dynamic evaluation results of EVA’s response capability of participating in DR are obtained.

1) RTM indicator: indicates the difference between the remaining parked time and the necessary charging time during the EV grid connection period. The mathematical definition is as follows:

RTMi=tidtSOCieSOCiQiηicpic(29)

where RTMi is the RTM of the i-th EV. The larger the value means the less urgent the EV charging demand is, the greater the regulation flexibility, and vice versa, the less the regulation flexibility.

2) SOC indicator: in addition to RTM indicator, SOC indicator also affects the generation of EV response priority queue. An EV with a larger SOC has limited rechargeable capacity but has a larger discharge capacity, so its regulation down response capability is smaller and its regulation up response capability is larger. Conversely, the EV with smaller SOC have larger regulation down response capability and smaller regulation up response capability. When EVA responds to ISO regulation instruction, it first generates EV response priority queue with RTM as the primary reference indicator in descending order, and if RTM is equal, EV response queue is then sorted with SOC as the secondary reference indicator. Specifically, if PkS>0, the EVA needs to provide regulation down capacity, then the EV with the larger RTM is regulated first, and if the RTM is equal, then the EV with the smaller SOC is dispatched first. Conversely, if PkS<0, the EVA needs to provide regulation up capacity, then the EV with the larger RTM is regulated first, and if the RTM is equal, then the EV with the larger SOC is dispatched first.

5.4 Response capability evaluation framework of EVA

The response capability evaluation flow chart of EVA is shown in Figure 4, with the following steps:

1) ISO issues DR time period t1,t2 according to the scheduling requirements.

2) EVA issues charging-discharging prices during DR time period, and EVA adopts differentiated billing or incentives for EV users of different response types.

3) Input EVs’ travel characteristics, battery information parameters, unidirectional/bidirectional EVs generating N number of random strategies under response constraints.

4) Output the evolutionarily stable strategy for each EV according to the solution method introduced in Section 4.3.

5) Based on the response capability evaluation of individual EVs, response capability of EVA is obtained by aggregation. EVA participates in the electricity market bidding based on the result of response capability evaluation, and finally determines the winning capacity and winning price by gaming with other interested entities in the market. EVA issues the charging-discharging price during DR time period to EVs based on the winning price to motivate EV users to participate in DR.

6) EVA responds to the scheduling instruction PkS of ISO at the time period k. Based on the response anticipation idea, the response priority queue is generated based on the RTM and SOC of EVs.

7) Filter i number of EVs dispatched in the response by condition, calculate the aggregated response capability of EVA, determine whether the relative error between the response instruction and the scheduling target instruction satisfies less than a constant ε, i.e., PkSPkR/PkSε. Continue to Step 8 if satisfied, or increase the response EVs recursively by the response priority queue if not satisfied, and i=i+1.

8) Update the status information of the EVs according to the regulation of the EVA, including the charging-discharging states and SOC values, and update the response capability of the EVA at time kT.

9) Determine by tt2 whether the DR time period is over, if the response is over then exit the cycle, if not then return to Step 6, and t=t1+Δt, k=k+1. Evaluate the variation in the EVA’s own response capability in the next time period due to the response to ISO’s scheduling instructions.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. Response capability evaluation flow chart of EVA.

6 Case studies

6.1 Parameter setting

The number of EVs Ni under the jurisdiction of EVA is assumed to be 1,000, and all EV battery parameters are set to be the same to simplify the model. The on-grid moments, off-grid moments, initial SOC at on-grid moments, and expected SOC at off-grid moments of EVs are mutually independent random variables whose probability distributions are obtained by function fitting based on real data of private car travel behavior and obey a normal distribution Nμ,σ2, where μ and σ are respectively expected value and standard deviation (Zheng et al., 2020). The main parameters in this paper are shown in Table 1. The charging and discharging power provided by the charging piles is set into seven levels: 7, −5, −3, 0, 3, 5, and 7 kW, with EV charging as positive and EV discharging as negative. The peak-to-valley electricity price in a region is shown in Table 2, and the DR time period as well as the charging-discharging price range issued by EVA is shown in Table 3.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Main parameters.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. The peak-valley time-of-use electricity price.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 3. Demand response period and electricity price range.

6.2 Analysis of the results of evolutionarily stable strategy

The focus of this paper is to evaluate the response capability of the EVA. It is assumed that after the EVA participates in the electricity market bid bidding, the incentive price issued for EVs during the DR time period based on the winning price is as follows: ¥0.4/kWh for unidirectional EV charging; ¥0.3/kWh for bidirectional EV charging and ¥1.5/kWh for discharging. In this paper, private cars have a long parked time, so the percentage of inelastic EVs is small. It is reasonable to assume that all EVs governed by EVA are unidirectional EVs or bidirectional EVs.

The 1,000 EVs are abstracted into 1,000 EV populations with the same travel characteristics, and the evolutionarily stable strategies of the 1,000 EVs are solved separately based on the evolutionary game model constructed in Section 4. For EVs with different response types, the set of 2,000 groups of charging-discharging power strategies and the initial selection ratio x0 for each strategy are randomly generated for each EV population separately under the constraints given in Section 3. Both the unidirectional EV and bidirectional EV percentages are set to 0.5, and the iteration step λ is 0.01. A certain unidirectional EV1 and bidirectional EV2 belonging to EVA are chosen as an example to show the evolutionary state change trend of their 2,000 groups of charging-discharging power strategies set, respectively, as shown in Figure 4. The evolutionary change curves of the average payment cost of the unidirectional EV1 and bidirectional EV2 populations are shown in Figure 5, and the travel behavior and evolutionarily stable strategies are shown in Table 4.

FIGURE 5
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 5. Strategy evolutionary state curve of EVs. (A) Strategy evolutionary state curve of EV1. (B) Strategy evolutionary state curve of EV2.

TABLE 4
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 4. EV1 and EV2 travel behaviors and evolutionarily stable strategies.

As can be seen from Figure 5, in the process of evolutionary game, the selection probability of only one set of strategy for each EV increases and gradually converges to 1, while the selection probability of other strategy sets gradually converges to 0. The strategy with the selection probability gradually converges to 1 is the evolutionarily stable strategy that EV finally chooses under the changing game environment. As shown in Figure 6 and Table 4, the average payment cost of EV population decreases with the increase of the number of iterations as the evolutionary game proceeds, and reaches stability at the game equilibrium, when the average payment cost of EV1 and EV2 populations are ¥15.8 and ¥7.2 respectively, indicating that EV will modify its own charging and discharging strategy with the goal of optimal utility function.

FIGURE 6
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 6. The average payment cost evolutionary curve of EVs.

The payment cost for 1,000 EVs with their respective evolutionarily stable strategies is shown in Figure 7. As can be seen from Figure 7, the payment cost of bidirectional EVs is lower compared to unidirectional EVs due to the lower incentive price of charging for bidirectional EVs and the discharge compensation when discharging. In addition, compared to the disordered charging strategy (EVs are charged to the expected power at rated power when they are connected to the grid), the charging cost of EVs with the evolutionarily stable strategy are all significantly lower, and there will even be some bidirectional EVs with positive benefits due to their participation in DR.

FIGURE 7
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 7. Charging cost comparison of EVs.

6.3 Response capability of EVA

The response capability of EVA is its adjustable range of power based on the baseline power. For display convenience, the regulation down response capability of the following result analysis is shown as positive and the regulation up response capability is shown as negative.

6.3.1 Comparison of methods

Most of the current EVA response capability evaluation methods treat EVs as directly controlled loads, ignoring the autonomy of EV users’ decision-making behavior. However, in realistic scenarios, EVA and EV users are different interest entities with different optimization goals in their respective decision-making processes. When evaluating the actual response capability of EVA, ignoring the autonomy of EV decision-making behavior may lead to overly idealized evaluation results.

The response capabilities of EVA based on different evaluation methods are compared below.

Proposed method: use evolutionary game theory to analyze the decision behavior of EV users in real-world scenarios and evaluate response capability of EVA on this basis.

Comparison method: EVs is considered as directly controlled loads, i.e., the method adopted by (Wu et al., 2018; Xu et al., 2023).

The response capability of EVA under different evaluation methods is shown in Figure 8.

FIGURE 8
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 8. Comparison of response capability under different evaluation methods.

As can be seen from Figure 8, the EVA response capability obtained by the comparison method is significantly larger, which is due to the over-idealization of the evaluation results caused by treating EV as a fully controllable load when evaluating the response capability of EVA. In the actual scenario, EVA does not necessarily have full control of EVs, therefore, the response capability of EVA obtained by the comparison method is not in line with the actual situation, and EVA may suffer large losses when bidding in the electricity market based on this evaluation results.

6.3.2 DR time period

In the actual scenario, ISO issues DR periods beforehand, EVA needs to evaluate the response capability under a given time period. To compare EVA’s response capability under different time periods, the following three scenarios are set:

Scenario 1 (scenario in this paper): peak shaving period: 19:00–21:00, valley filling period: 23:00–3:00.

Scenario 2: peak shaving period: 19:00–22:00, valley filling period: 23:00–3:00.

Scenario 3: peak shaving period: 19:00–23:00, valley filling period: 23:00–3:00.

The comparative analysis of EVA’s response capability under different DR time periods is shown in Figure 9. From Figure 9, it can be seen that EVA has greater regulation down response capacity during peak shaving hours and greater regulation up response capacity during valley filling hours, which is due to the autonomy of EV decision-making considered when evaluating response capability of EVA. EV users will choose to discharge at high prices and charge at low prices for their own economic benefits, more EVs are in discharge state during peak shaving hours and the baseline power is negative, so EVs will have a greater regulation up response capability, while the opposite is observed during valley filling hours. In addition, it can be seen from Figure 9 that the response capability of EVA under different time periods differs if the actual scenario needs to extend the peak shaving DR period, because the number of EVs connected under different time periods is different from their charging-discharging states and SOCs. EVA only needs to issue DR time periods and incentive prices to evaluate the response capability of EVA under different given DR time periods based on the model built in this paper.

FIGURE 9
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 9. Comparison of response capability under different time periods.

6.3.3 Charging-discharging incentive price

The charging-discharging incentive price affects the EVA’s response capability during the DR period. In order to compare the EVA’s response capability under different incentive prices, the following 2 scenarios are set:

Scenario 1 (scenario in this paper): the charging price is ¥0.4/kWh for unidirectional EV, the charging price is ¥0.3/kWh and the discharging price is ¥1.5/kWh for bidirectional EV.

Scenario 2: the charging price is ¥0.35/kWh for unidirectional EV, the charging price is ¥0.25/kWh and the discharging price is ¥1.8/kWh for bidirectional EV.

The comparative analysis of the response capability of EVA under different incentive prices is shown in Figure 10. From Figure 10, it can be seen that EVA has larger regulation down response capability in peak shaving hours and larger regulation up response capability in valley filling hours under scenario 2 compared to scenario 1. This is due to the lower incentive charging price and higher incentive discharging price given in Scenario 2. The baseline power of EVA shows a more obvious buying low and selling high characteristics during peak shaving and valley filling hours, and the different baseline power of EVA in DR hours leads to different response capability of EVA. However, the difference of EVA’s response capability in the two scenarios is not large. EVA should reasonably set the charging-discharging incentive price according to the scheduling requirements in order to avoid blindly increasing the incentive price to affect its own revenue.

FIGURE 10
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 10. Comparison of response capability under different incentive prices.

6.3.4 Percentage of unidirectional/bidirectional EVs

To compare the response capability of EVA under different types of EV percentages, the following three scenarios are set:

Scenario 1: bidirectional EV percentage of 100%.

Scenario 2 (scenario in this paper): unidirectional EV and bidirectional EV percentage of 50% each.

Scenario 3: unidirectional EV percentage of 100%.

The comparative analysis of EVA’s response capability under different types of EV percentage is shown in Figure 11. From Figure 11, it can be seen that with the increase of bidirectional EV percentage, the regulation up response capability of EVA increases significantly. Therefore, in the system with shortage of regulation up response capability, corresponding incentives can be developed to mobilize the EV users’ discharge enthusiasm and increase the bidirectional EV percentage.

FIGURE 11
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 11. Comparison of response capability under different types of EV percentage.

6.3.5 Dynamic update of EVA’s response capability

The dynamic update of EVA’s response capability in response to ISO scheduling instructions is shown in Figure 12. As can be seen from Figure 12, EVA can accurately track the scheduling target instructions issued by ISO and realize the dynamic update of EVA’s response capability. It is worth noting that due to the short DR response period, EVA participation in DR will not reach its own capacity boundary, so the change of response capability boundary is not obvious and EVA can play the role of providing short time power support for the system.

FIGURE 12
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 12. Dynamic update of EVA’s response capability.

7 Conclusion

In this paper, a response capability evaluation model of EVA based on the idea of evolutionary game and response anticipation is proposed, and the validity of the model is verified by simulation, and the main conclusions obtained are as follows:

(1) Considering EV users as highly autonomous individuals with “bounded rationality” and “limited information”, an evolutionary game model with multi-strategy sets of EVs is constructed. On this basis, the response capability of EVs before participating in DR is evaluated, avoiding the over-idealized results of EVA’s response capability evaluation caused by ignoring the autonomy of EV decision-making behavior.

(2) EVA’s response capability is affected by the DR time period window, charging-discharging incentive price and the percentage of different types of EVs to different degrees. Based on the model built in this paper, EVA’s response capability can be accurately evaluated under different scenarios, and the evaluation results can be used as the basis for EVA to participate in electricity market bidding.

(3) A regulation strategy is proposed for EVA to generate EV response priority queue according to RTM and SOC indexes. Based on the idea of response anticipation, the response capability of EVA is dynamically updated after participating in DR, and the simulation results show that EVA can accurately track the scheduling target instructions issued by ISO and can play the role of providing short-time power support for the power system.

The focus of the follow-up research is to study the optimization strategy of EVA to participate in the electricity market based on the proposed response capability evaluation model, in order to achieve win-win and coordinated development among ISO, EVA and EV users.

Data availability statement

The raw data supporting the conclusion of this article will be made available by the authors, without undue reservation.

Author contributions

XX: methodology, conception, writing—review and editing, ZM: project administration and supervision, ZZ: software, writing, and formal analysis, LJ: software and data analysis. All authors contributed to the article and approved the submitted version.

Funding

This work was supported by the Research and Application of Key Technologies of Virtual Power Plant under Electricity Market Environment (CHDKJ21-01-107), and by the National Key R&D Program of China (2018YFE0122200).

Conflict of interest

LJ was employed by Nanjing SAC Power Grid Automation Co., Ltd.

The remaining authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Abapour, S., Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B., and Hagh, M. (2019b). A bayesian game theoretic based bidding strategy for demand response aggregators in electricity markets. Sustain. Cities Soc. 54, 101787. doi:10.1016/j.scs.2019.101787

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Abapour, S., Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B., and Hagh, M. (2019a). Robust bidding strategy for demand response aggregators in electricity market based on game theory. J. Clean. Prod. 243 (1), 118393. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.118393

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cai, G., Jiang, Y., Huang, N., Yang, D., Pan, X., and Shang, W. (2023). Large-scale electric vehicles charging and discharging optimization scheduling based on multi-agent two-level game under electricity demand response mechanism. Proc. CSEE 43 (04), 85–99. doi:10.13334/j.0258-8013.pcsee.212528

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., Chen, Y., and Liu, G. (2022). 2PnS-EG: A general two-population n-strategy evolutionary game for strategic long-term bidding in a deregulated market under different market clearing mechanisms. Int. J. Electr. Eng. 142, 108182. doi:10.1016/j.ijepes.2022.108182

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., Liu, G., Huang, H., Wang, X., Chen, Y., Zhang, J., et al. (2020a). Equilibrium analysis of general N-population multi-strategy games for generation-side long-term bidding: An evolutionary game perspective. J. Clean. Prod. 276, 124123. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124123

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., Yang, R., Liu, G., Wang, J., Chen, Y., Wang, X., et al. (2020b). Muti-population asymmetric evolutionary game dynamics and its applications in power demand-side response in smart grid. Proc. CSEE 40 (S1), 20–36. doi:10.13334/j.0258-8013.pcsee.200930

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., Yin, L., Wang, J., Shen, T., Chen, Y., Liu, G., et al. (2021). Behavioral decision-making in power demand-side response management: A multi-population evolutionary game dynamics perspective. Int. J. Electr. Eng. 129, 106743. doi:10.1016/j.ijepes.2020.106743

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., and Yu, T. (2019a). A new generation of ai: A review and perspective on machine learning technologies applied to smart energy and electric power systems. Int. J. Energy Res. 43, 1928–1973. doi:10.1002/er.4333

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cheng, L., and Yu, T. (2019b). Smart dispatching for energy internet with complex cyber- physical- social systems: A parallel dispatch perspective. Int. J. Energy Res. 43, 3080–3133. doi:10.1002/er.4384

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chukwu, U., and Mahajan, S. (2014). V2G parking lot with PV rooftop for capacity enhancement of a distribution system. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 5 (1), 119–127. doi:10.1109/TSTE.2013.2274601

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Deng, R., Yue, X., Huo, D., Liu, Y., Huang, Y., Huang, C., et al. (2020). Exploring flexibility of electric vehicle aggregators as energy reserve. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 184 (3), 106305. doi:10.1016/j.epsr.2020.106305

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Fang, D., Zhao, C., and Yu, Q. (2018). Government regulation of renewable energy generation and transmission in China’s electricity market. Renew. Sustain. energy Rev. 45, 775–793. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2018.05.039

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Han, B., Lu, S., Xue, F., and Jiang, L. (2019). Day-ahead electric vehicle aggregator bidding strategy using stochastic programming in an uncertain reserve market. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 13 (12), 2517–2525. doi:10.1049/iet-gtd.2018.6951

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Han, S., Han, S., and Sezaki, K. (2011). Estimation of achievable power capacity from plug-in electric vehicles for V2G frequency regulation: Case studies for market participation. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2 (4), 632–641. doi:10.1109/TSG.2011.2160299

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hong, Q., Meng, F., Liu, J., and Bo, R. (2023). A bilevel game-theoretic decision-making framework for strategic retailers in both local and wholesale electricity markets. Appl. Energy 330 (6), 120311. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2022.120311

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hu, J., Wu, J., Ai, X., and Liu, N. (2021). Coordinated energy management of prosumers in a distribution system considering network congestion. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 12 (1), 468–478. doi:10.1109/TSG.2020.3010260

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

International Energy Agency (2021). Global EV Outlook 2021. [Internet]. Website; Apr [cited 2023 May 12]. Available at: https://www.iea.org/reports/global-ev-outlook-2021.

Google Scholar

Lam, A., Leung, K., and Li, V. (2016). Capacity estimation for vehicle-to-grid frequency regulation services with smart charging mechanism. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 7 (1), 156–166. doi:10.1109/TSG.2015.2436901

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, C., Song, Y., Wang, W., and Shi, X. (2023). The governance of manufacturers’ greenwashing behaviors: A tripartite evolutionary game analysis of electric vehicles. Appl. Energy 333, 120498. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2022.120498

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, H., Lian, H., Ge, S., Zhang, K., Tang, C., Zhao, H., et al. (2017). Removal of integrated hepatitis B virus DNA using CRISPR-cas9. Auto. Elect. Power Syst. 41 (8), 91–97. doi:10.3389/fcimb.2017.00091

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Meng, F., and Zeng, X. (2016). A profit maximization approach to demand response management with customers behavior learning in smart grid. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 7 (3), 1516–1529. doi:10.1109/TSG.2015.2462083

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shariatzadeh, F., Mandal, P., and Srivastava, A. (2015). Demand response for sustainable energy systems: A review, application and implementation strategy. Renew. Sustain. energy Rev. 45, 343–350. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2015.01.062

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Weibull, J. (2015). Evolutionary game theory. Translated by Wang, Y. Shanghai: Shanghai People’s Publishing House, 30–59.

Google Scholar

Wu, F., Yang, J., Zhan, X., Liao, S., and Xu, J. (2021). The online charging and discharging scheduling potential of electric vehicles considering the uncertain responses of users. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 36 (3), 1794–1806. doi:10.1109/TPWRS.2020.3029836

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wu, J., Xue, Y., Xie, D., Yue, D., Wen, F., Zhao, J., et al. (2018). Magnetic resonance imaging and molecular features associated with tumor-infiltrating lymphocytes in breast cancer. Auto. Elect. Power Syst. 42 (13), 101–107+168. doi:10.1186/s13058-018-1039-2

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Xu, X., Mi, Z., Yu, S., Zhan, Z., and Ji, L. (2023). Spatial-temporal response capability probabilistic evaluation method of electric vehicle aggregator based on trip characteristics modelling. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 17 (9), 2192–2206. doi:10.1049/gtd2.12788

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, B., and Kezunovic, M. (2016). Impact on power system flexibility by electric vehicle participation in ramp market. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 7 (3), 1285–1294. doi:10.1109/TSG.2015.2437911

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, H., Hu, Z., Xu, Z., and Song, Y. (2017). Evaluation of achievable vehicle-to-grid capacity using aggregate PEV model. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 32 (1), 784–794. doi:10.1109/TPWRS.2016.2561296

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, Y., Mu, Y., Jia, H., Wang, M., Zhou, Y., and Xu, Z. (2019). Response capability evaluation model with multiple time scales for electric vehicle virtual power plant. Auto. Elect. Power Syst. 43 (12), 94–103. doi:10.7500/AEPS20180731009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zheng, Y., Yu, H., Shao, Z., and Jian, L. (2020). Day-ahead bidding strategy for electric vehicle aggregator enabling multiple agent modes in uncertain electricity markets. Appl. Energy 280 (2), 115977. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2020.115977

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zheng, Z., Zhao, X., Wang, S., Yu, Q., Zhang, H., Li, Z., et al. (2023). Extension coordinated control of distributed-driven electric vehicles based on evolutionary game theory. Control. Eng. Pract. 137, 105583. doi:10.1016/j.conengprac.2023.105583

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nomenclature

Keywords: electric vehicle, electric vehicle aggregator, evolutionary game, response anticipation, response capability evaluation

Citation: Xu X, Mi Z, Zhan Z and Ji L (2023) Response capability evaluation model of electric vehicle aggregator based on evolutionary game and response anticipation. Front. Energy Res. 11:1225327. doi: 10.3389/fenrg.2023.1225327

Received: 19 May 2023; Accepted: 12 July 2023;
Published: 28 July 2023.

Edited by:

Ji Wu, Hefei University of Technology, China

Reviewed by:

Lefeng Cheng, Guangzhou University, China
Fanlin Meng, The University of Manchester, United Kingdom

Copyright © 2023 Xu, Mi, Zhan and Ji. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Xiangchu Xu, xxcncepu@gmail.com

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.