Skip to main content

POLICY AND PRACTICE REVIEWS article

Front. Energy Res., 09 February 2022
Sec. Sustainable Energy Systems
This article is part of the Research Topic Energy Efficiency and Residential Energy Consumption: Current Challenges, Policies and Emerging Trends View all 5 articles

Promoting Energy Efficiency: Barriers, Societal Needs and Policies

  • European Commission, Joint Research Centre, Ispra, Italy

The Climate Change urgency requires a swift reduction of energy consumption. One way to achieve this is through increased energy efficiency. Over the past decades, the debate on how to encourage energy efficiency has been guided by the physical–technical–economic model, which has a strong focus on technologies and cost savings, and in which human behaviour has been seen as a trivial factor. However, the advent of behavioural economics has started enabling the integration of the human factor also into energy efficiency policy. Still, this integration is only in its infancy. While the perspectives taken by economics and behavioural sciences enable to capture the individual dimension of energy efficiency as a problem of individual choice, the collective and social aspect of energy efficiency is still largely overlooked on the energy policy agenda. With its emphasis on how social structures interpenetrate individual actions and construction of reality, sociology offers an additional important insight that goes beyond the identification of barriers-drivers underlying investment choices. This paper aims to increase policy makers’ awareness of complementary disciplinary resources, on which they can draw to better define and address the problems associated to energy efficiency. Second, it provides a case to develop an interdisciplinary perspective as a basis to develop a more scientifically valid and socially relevant energy efficiency policy advice.

Introduction

The Paris Agreement calls for a stabilisation of global temperature within this century well below 2 C. This will require a swift reduction of energy consumption. In this fight against climate change, the pivotal role that energy efficiency (EE) plays is recognised worldwide. In particular, EE is seen as a “win-win” solution, enabling not only to reduce greenhouse emissions and investments in energy infrastructures, but also to improve citizens’ budgeting capacities (Stadelmann, 2017; Taylor et al., 2010) and wellbeing, including the reduction of energy poverty (Fawcett and Killip, 2019). Prominent institutions, such as the IPCC1 and the IEA2, have acknowledged EE as a means to curb energy demand and enhance energy savings. Notably, the European Union has identified EE as a priority in the decarbonisation scenarios advanced in the Energy Roadmap 20503 and in the European Green Deal4, where a 50% reduction of the final energy consumed is expected compared to 2005. A large portion of this reduction is expected to be achieved in the building sector, in particular in the residential sector. This is due to the fact that 40% of the total EU final consumption is associated to the building sector, where residential buildings account for 25% (Tsemekidi Tzeiranaki et al., 2019).

The EE policy goal is not free from challenges. In particular, the actual rate of adoption of EE lags far behind the rate suggested by cost and potential studies and the cost/benefits analyses, which assume that citizens always choose the most profitable option for themselves (Nauclér and Enkvist, 2009), the so-called energy efficiency gap (Hirst and Brown, 1990; Jaffe and Stavins, 1994). However, as Stern (Stern and Stern, 2007) stated, ‘it is difficult to explain low take up of EE as purely a rational response to investment under uncertainty’.

Being unable to explain this gap as a purely economic phenomenon, scientists have extensively investigated the decision-making process related to EE investments, especially at individual level, adopting different disciplinary perspectives (reviewed by, e.g., (Lutzenhiser, 1993; Wilson and Dowlatabadi, 2007; Lopes et al., 2012; Schleich et al., 2016). However, despite such multidisciplinary contributions, EE policy has mostly been guided by perspectives focusing on costs, discount rates, drivers and barriers, disregarding other factors accounting for the interconnection between social systems and people (Lutzenhiser, 2014) or overlooking how citizens actually think about the problem of efficiency in energy use (Labanca and Bertoldi, 2018). This suggests that EE policy would highly benefit from including sociological perspectives.

Without a lens enabling to capture the connection between social structures (like social classes) and justice, EE policy interventions might not only worsen existing inequalities (Sovacool, 2021), but also fail to reflect society’s needs (Pereira and Saltelli, 2017). Therefore, EE policy should also aim to be guided by perspectives explicitly accounting for social issues, like those retaining knowledge as socially constructed (Lutzenhiser, 2014). However, integrating multiple perspectives and translating them into practice is challenging, because of an “information gap” in policy on how to best apply policy (Axon et al., 2018).

This paper aims to contribute to close this “information gap” by increasing policy makers’ awareness of the co-existence of complementary disciplinary social science perspectives to better define and address EE challenges at individual level5.

The paper first outlines the current concepts and interventions used to understand and promote EE investments. Then, in Section 3, it introduces the sociological perspective as a complementary perspective on which EE policy-makers can draw. Section 4 outlines a call for a more interdisciplinary perspective to inform EE policy. Finally Section 5 concludes.

The Current Approach to EE Policy-Making

The problem of the EE gap has been a prominent topic in energy policy debates, given that its reduction is assumed to provide “win-win” opportunities, creating a need to identify the potential causes and select the right instrument for policy interventions (Allcott and Greenstone, 2012; Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015). As an example, in the European Union the focus on the EE gap has been dominating since the nineties, resulting in the adoption of several programmes to remove barriers to optimal energy efficiency investments (Labanca and Bertoldi, 2018; Economidou et al., 2020).

Within this frame, policy makers strived to adopt the scientific approach to policy-making, informed both by the evidence provided by scientific theories to understand how to address the EE gap (the so-called evidence-based approach), and stakeholders’ consultation and lobbying mediated with policy priorities.

These official policy-making narratives, assuming citizens’ participation in the public sphere through optimal decisions that policy makers should enable, not only placed emphasis on individual behaviour change (Lennon et al., 2020), but also shaped the demand for useful scientific insights, in particular those assuming the individual as an abstract entity reacting to policies with changes in their discount rate and disjointed from a complex society (Batel et al., 2016).

For decades, energy policy has been mainly informed by science, technology, engineering and mathematics (STEM) disciplines, as a response to the diffused narrative pushing for technology development (Sovacool et al., 2015), discounting other studies in energy-related social sciences highlighting how fundamental the human and social factors are in shaping energy demand (Lutzenhiser, 1993; Wilhite et al., 2000).

Fortunately, with the exception of (neoclassical) economics, which has always been treated as the most “sciency” of the social sciences and thus entitled to inform the policy table as a STEM subject, social science disciplines (such as behavioural sciences) have now recently started feeding into the energy policy debates by incorporating the human factor (Foulds and Robison, 2018).

Because EE adoption is understood as an optimal investment decision that individuals often fail to make (Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015), the insights from economics and lately also from behavioural sciences6 (Foulds and Robison, 2018; Loewenstein and Chater, 2017) have been instrumental to identify the decisional barriers and drivers underlying the EE gap, and the instruments required to close it. In the following subsections, we present an overview of these barriers and drivers (see Table 1, Section 2.1 and Section 2.2), and instruments (see Tables 2, 3 and Section 2.3), resulting from a narrative review based on the categorizations of previous studies (e.g. Jackson, 2005; Wilson and Dowlatabadi, 2007; Gillingham et al., 2009; Gillingham and Palmer, 2014; Bertoldi, 2020) and the authors’ experience working at the interface between science and energy efficiency policy for 30 years.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. “Summary of barriers and drivers”.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. “Summary of Traditional Interventions promoting EE adoption”.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 3. “Summary of nudges and boosts promoting EE”.

Barriers to EE Investments

Market Failures

In neoclassical economics, investing in EE is assumed to be a discrete choice, and individuals are assumed to choose the appliance only if that is the most rational option available. In doing so, individuals are assumed to be capable to take into account the benefits that the service accrues, even though these energy savings are delayed in the future. An implication of these assumptions is that completely rational individuals would always choose to invest in EE, given that this is economically optimal. However, they fail to invest in EE because of the way the market is structured (Gillingham et al., 2009). Some of the current market barriers are the result of “market failures,” which are assumed to need to be corrected (Bertoldi, 2020):

i) imperfect information (individuals lack or have imperfect knowledge on EE, and collecting information is generally not free (transaction costs (Sanstad and Howarth, 1994));

ii) split incentives (these arise when the tenant has incomplete information about the service (EE of the building), and the landlord underinvests in the EE of the property, for fear of being unable to recoup the costs of investments through rent (Gillingham et al., 2012; Palm and Reindl, 2018; Cattaneo, 2019));

iii) credit constraints (individuals do not have enough financial resources or access to the necessary credit to sustain the high up-front costs (Golove and Eto, 1996));

iv) regulatory failures (energy prices might fail to reflect their true cost, due to regulatory failures or non-inclusion of negative externalities, like pollution (Brown, 2001)).

Yet, market failures are not the sole reason why individuals fail to invest in EE (Stern and Stern, 2007).

Behavioural Failures

Neoclassical economics proved to model human behaviour unsatisfactorily and to be invalid to make policy predictions. Therefore, for the past few decades, the scientific and policy debates have started exploiting a new framework that explains the factors that cause behaviour: behavioural economics (Camerer, 2003). Within this framework, additional barriers emerged as factors preventing individuals to invest in EE: “behavioural failures”7. These are the result of the way individuals cope with complex decisions (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). In particular, as individuals are bounded rational (Simon, 1955, 1957), they use shortcuts, the so-called heuristics, but often these lead individuals to make suboptimal decisions, such as failing to optimally invest in EE. Here, we provide an overview of the behavioural failures explaining why individuals do not invest in EE (under the categorisation of (DellaVigna, 2009), non-standard preferences, non-standard beliefs and non-standard decision-making).

Non-Standard Preferences (Reference-Dependent Preferences, Present-Biased Preferences)

Due to loss aversion8, individuals are less willing to invest in EE if they perceive the investment could generate a potential loss (such as less comfort, or lack of energy savings (Heutel, 2019)). Individuals can also be less willing to invest in EE because of their limited ability of planning ahead (Ballinger et al., 2003) or debt aversion (Schleich et al., 2019), given that investing in EE is associated to benefits that will materialize in the future.

Non-Standard Decision-Making (Status Quo Bias, Limited Attention)

Due to status quo bias9, individuals might prefer to maintain and overuse the current stock of appliances instead of investing in EE (Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015). This is particularly true when a psychological commitment to costly investments exists (sunk cost fallacy), culminating in an overuse of current appliances to amortize investment costs (Blasch and Daminato, 2020). In addition, individuals might decide not to invest in EE because their choice is driven by the salient attributes of the available information (DellaVigna, 2009), like high up-front prices.

Non-Standard Beliefs (Incorrect Beliefs About the Future)

Individuals are less likely to invest in EE, when they have incorrect beliefs over the future benefits of an energy efficient technology (Allcott and Greenstone, 2012).

Drivers of EE Investments

Pro-Environmental Preferences

The empirical and experimental evidence underlying behavioural economics proved that, in addition to displaying cognitive deviations from rational choice assumptions, individuals also display motivational deviations: namely their degree of self-interest and motivations can differ (Sacco and Zarri, 2003). For the EE case, this heterogeneity in motivations suggests that there might be additional non-economic drivers of the decision to invest. More specifically, a difference can occur in the ways individuals care about the environment (i.e. they display “pro-environmental preferences”) (Schleich et al., 2016), due to (Frey and Stutzer, 2006)) 1) impure altruism (“warm glow”10 (Andreoni, 1989)), 2) pure altruism (“pro-social orientation”11 (Bénabou and Tirole, 2006)), 3) personal norms12, (Festinger, 1957; Akerlof and Kranton, 2000) and 4) social norms13 (Elster, 1989; Bicchieri, 2005).

Assessing the underlying motivations behind why individuals care about the environment is also crucial to understanding sources of rebound effects (Ruzzenenti and Bertoldi, 2017; Belaïd et al., 2020). For example, in addition to the reduced service cost arising from technological improvements, an additional potential source of rebound effects is moral licensing (Dütschke et al., 2018), which “occurs when past moral behaviour makes people more likely to do potentially immoral things without worrying about feeling or appearing immoral” (Monin and Jordan, 2009). Therefore, if individuals are motivated to invest in EE because they attach a moral value to it (i.e. they think that is the right thing to do), it is likely that there will be higher rebound effects following their investment decision (i.e. they will feel entitled to consume more electricity to heat their apartment or to adopt an inefficient appliance later on).

Antecedents

While the (neoclassical and behavioural) economic models focus on the features characterising the decision situation and the incentive structure that might promote or inhibit the decision to invest in EE, the psychological perspective often focuses on uncovering the antecedents driving behaviour. Below we provide an overview of the antecedents, which fits the categorisation of (Steg and Vlek, 2009) (intentions, moral and norms, and emotions). In doing so, we focus only on some exemplary psychological theories.

Intentions

Within the Theory of Planned Behaviour (TPB, (Ajzen, 1991)), behaviour is the result of a deliberate process where individuals compare the costs and benefits associated to a certain choice, and the key driver of behaviour is the “intention” to act. More specifically, “intention to act” is influenced by:

- Attitude towards behaviour, which results from the individual beliefs and the evaluation of consequences associated to the behaviour;

- Perceived behavioural control, which is the perceived difficulty to engage in behaviour;

- Subjective norm, which is the perceived (dis)approval of behaviour by relevant reference persons (e.g. family, friends, colleagues).

Under this theory, individuals are more willing to invest in EE if 1) their beliefs and evaluation of the consequences of EE are positive, 2) they perceive the investment as a doable task, and 3) they think their relevant peers will approve of it.

Values, Norms and Morals

Another key driver of pro-environmental behaviour according to Stern and Dietz (Stern and Dietz, 1994), and Schultz (Schultz, 2001) are “values.” In particular, individuals who display altruistic, prosocial, self-transcendent and biospheric values (Nordlund and Garvill, 2002; De Groot and Steg, 2010); Schultz and Zelezny, 1999, Ateş, 2020) are more willing to invest in EE.

Similarly, individuals who display moral obligation towards the environment are more willing to invest in EE (Value Beliefs Norms Theory, VBN (Stern, 2000)). This is activated by the level of responsibility that one wants to assume towards the environment, prompted by the awareness of the consequences of his/her own action on the environment, which is directly related to one’s core values.

A driver related to personal norms and values is social norms. According to the theory of Normative Conduct (Cialdini et al., 1990, 1991), social norms operate through two distinct channels: descriptive (what most people do) and injunctive (what ought to be done). When these norms are salient, they can drive EE investments, e.g. when individuals know that their relevant peers have already invested in EE (Cialdini and Goldstein, 2004).

Emotions

By acting as filters for new information, “emotions” enable to focus attention on goals, needs and values, and set the stage for subsequent behaviours. Therefore, when information prompts positive emotions, it can lead individuals to engage in pro-environmental behaviours, such as investing in EE (Brosch et al., 2014).

Encouraging EE Investments

The extensive literature on EE policy evaluation (for reviews of this literature, see, e.g., (Gillingham et al., 2009; Tietenberg, 2009; Gillingham and Palmer, 2014) proves that several public policies have been implemented to promote EE mainly informed by insights from economics and more recently from behavioural sciences too (Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015; Foulds and Robison, 2018).

In particular, with the advent of behavioural economics, the reasons for intervening at the policy level could rely no longer only on economic grounds (to correct market failures), but also on behavioural grounds (to correct behavioural failures) (Loewenstein and Chater, 2017; Belaïd and Joumni, 2020). Since then, across the world, including in Europe (Baggio et al., 2021), insights from behavioural sciences started to be incorporated in the implementation of traditional instruments to augment their efficacy (Loewenstein and Chater, 2017), and to enrich the policy toolbox with additional instruments in several policy areas (Sousa Lourenco et al., 2016). However, these approaches often take individuals in isolation from specific contexts (Foulds and Robison, 2018). In the following section we provide an overview of the instruments promoting EE.

Financial Instruments

Financial incentives consist of subsidies, tax credits, tax deductions, rebates or loan subsidies (Gillingham et al., 2009; Bertoldi et al., 2021.). Traditionally, these were implemented with the assumption that individuals would be more willing to invest in EE if financial motivation was provided to cope with high-up front costs. However, insights from behavioural sciences suggest that individuals are not only sensitive to monetary incentives of taxes and subsidies, but also to how these are framed. As an example, subsidies and tax credits can be more effective than an equivalent tax (Hassett and Metcalf, 1995; Bertoldi et al., 2013).

Insights from behavioural sciences also suggest that the effectiveness of financial incentives depends on the motivations they target. As an example, the provision of an extrinsic (monetary) motivation to invest in EE could have a backfiring effect on those individuals who are already intrinsically motivated (e.g. because of altruism and warm glow) to invest in EE (Frey and others, 1997; Gneezy and Rustichini, 2000). Therefore, an effective intervention preventing such a crowding-out effect would complement financial incentives with messages that crowd-in intrinsic motivation, like those encouraging to invest in EE as a way to protect the environment (Hilton et al., 2014).

Regulatory Instruments

By imposing bans on products that do not meet certain criteria, regulatory instruments change the options available to consumers. In the context of EE, these have been implemented as product standards, in order to set a minimum level of EE, like for HVAC systems and insulation measures (Cass and Shove, 2018), and light bulbs (Frondel and Lohmann, 2011). As standards are usually implemented based on ex-ante estimates of cost and benefits (i.e. energy savings) resulting from implicit modelling assumptions on individual behaviour, they do not usually consider welfare losses from reduced available options or the rebound effect. Insights from behavioural sciences, like that individuals display non-standard time preferences, can be incorporated in the evaluation of welfare effects and better informs the choice of standards (Tsvetanov and Segerson, 2014).

Informational Instruments

Information instruments disclose technical information, such as energy savings, mainly through labels, audits and information programs. These were traditionally implemented with the assumption that individuals would be more willing to invest in EE if provided with more information. However, insights from behavioural sciences point that individuals are not only sensitive to the availability of relevant information, but also to how it is framed. These insights from behavioural sciences can magnify the impact of informational interventions, by improving the presentation of “decision-relevant information” (Münscher et al., 2016), such as making operating costs salient at the point of purchase (Newell and Siikamäki, 2014).

Nudges

Insights from behavioural sciences have enriched the policy toolbox with additional instruments, such as nudges14. These enable to directly address the behavioural failures preventing individuals to execute on their intentions to invest in EE, by altering the decision structure or by assisting the decision (Münscher et al., 2016). An exemplary nudge is changing the effort required to select the desired policy option. This can be achieved for example by furnishing new buildings with energy-saving light bulbs by default (Alberini et al., 2013), or by decreasing the perceived financial effort to invest in EE (Münscher et al., 2016). Changing the decision structure by connecting the choice of options with social consequences (Münscher et al., 2016), like enabling to increase social status (Griskevicius et al., 2010), can also be an effective nudge to promote EE investments. Nudges that assist decision makers are commitment devices, reminders and goal settings (Münscher et al., 2016). As an example, sending reminders with information on the date and time of energy audits can be an effective way to increase the final audit uptake (Gillingham and Tsvetanov, 2018). Also, providing individuals with a planning aid or prompting them to make a plan can be effective at helping individuals switch to more energy efficient appliances (Madrian, 2014).

Boosts

Differently from nudges, boosts are interventions that do not target behaviour, but competencies, with the aim to empower individuals to make complex decisions (Grüne-Yanoff and Hertwig, 2016; Hertwig, 2017; Hertwig and Ryall, 2020), like investing in EE. As an example, training providing some basic financial concepts, in addition to knowledge on energy-related issues, can boost the necessary skills to make complex calculations, helping appreciate the benefits of EE and make a well-informed investment decision (Blasch et al., 2017).

A Complementary Approach to Inform EE Policy-making

Scientists’ and policy makers’ debates so far have predominantly focused on the EE problem of suboptimal adoption (Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015). Reflecting a positivist approach to social problems, where the aim is to find their causal factors and potential cure (Harris, 2013), these debates aimed to identify the factors that cause individuals to (fail to) invest in EE (Shove, 2010), focusing on individual choice. However, positivism is not the only approach to understand reality. The constructionist approach advanced by the sociological analysis of social problems seeks to understand how problems are socially constructed (Heiner, 2002). As an example, the problem that citizens are expected to make optimal consumption decisions for themselves and the environment can be constructed by the institutionalization of individualizing approaches (Batel et al., 2016).

The sociological perspective underlines that, having evolved to live in societies, individuals are not actors that make decisions independently from their context, but “encultured” actors (Hoff and Stiglitz, 2016). Preferences, perceptions and values are not exogenously given, but endogenously shaped by the places to which individuals are accustomed. These places produce mental models, meanings, worldviews and narratives that “shape the way we attend to, interpret, remember, and respond emotionally to the information we encounter and possess” ((DiMaggio, 1997), p. 274).

In sociology, the focus is, thus, not on individual choice, but on social structures, such as laws, cultures and habitual practices of meaningful groups, and socially-designed physical structures (Galvin, 2020), as these shape how individuals think, what they want and what they do (Giddens, 1979, 1984). With its emphasis on the construction of reality and generation of meanings, the constructivist approach contrasts the positivist one, which assumes reality as objective (Alvesson and Skoldberg, 2009). In particular, by opining that reality is constructed by the observer, it suggests that there might be a multiplicity of constructed, even contradictory, realities (Aliyu et al., 2014). As for the problem of EE, not only different experts, but also laypeople, might have different perspectives on EE, shaped by the meanings and representations of the groups they are part of (Batel et al., 2016). Similarly to scientists, who see problems through their intellectual frameworks made of scientific norms that shape their way of knowing (Mauser et al., 2013), the knowledge of laypeople is not necessarily idiosyncratic, but mediated by their specific-context experience (Ingold, 2011). Therefore, uncovering the multiplicity of these perspectives on EE might enable to provide a deeper understanding of how EE can be conceived as a problem or solution.

By tracking how social structures interpenetrate individual actions and social issues, the sociological lens can enable policy makers to become more aware of the connection between social structures and justice issues (Sovacool and Dworkin, 2015). As an example, policy makers can recognise that certain groups of individuals are disproportionately affected by the legacy of an unjust social structure (e.g. classes, identities) and thus advance more justice-aware policies (Sovacool et al., 2017).

The following section illustrates how focusing on social structures enables to capture the social construction of how individuals understand and practice EE. To do so, we use two exemplary social structures, which have received particular attention in the energy-sociological academic debate.

Social Structures

Practices

Practices are an example of social structures and the focus of Social practice theory (Shove et al., 2012). While the words “behaviour” and “practice” are often used interchangeably (Shove, 2010), and recently behaviour change has also been approached through the adoption of “a practice lens” (DellaValle et al., 2018), practices differ from the positivist conceptualisation of behaviour, being emergent, endogenous and dynamic social entities that capture their carriers (people) and that, at the same time, need a sufficient number of carriers to constantly reproduce them (Shove, 2003).

There are different approaches to understand the key elements of practices and among those that have received great attention in the energy-sociological debate the one advanced by Shove stands out. Within this approach, energy is not used for its own sake, but is part of accomplishing practices, like keeping warm and cool, which people value as aspects of their everyday life (Warde, 2005). Therefore, rather than seeing one-shot decisions as decontextualised, the practices associated to EE are analysed through the lens of the routines and activities shared with family and friends that constitute life at home (Wilson et al., 2015). In particular, practices can be understood by looking at the physical aspects of performing a practice (material-structure), meanings associated to the practice, and competences needed to perform the practice (Shove and Pantzar, 2005).

Tracking the constituents of socially shared energy practices might enable policy makers not only to acknowledge different representations underlying energy demand (Hargreaves and Middlemiss, 2020), but also to understand how to reorganise technological outputs and associated shared meanings and competences in a socially relevant way (Labanca and Bertoldi, 2018). When a practice is socially valid, people need to feel competent in performing it, under the fear of being stigmatised (Hards, 2013). As an example, in warm (cold) climates, it is key for a host to being able to keep their home cold(warm) (Wilhite and Lutzenhiser, 1999; Hitchings and Lee, 2008). Therefore, when practices are technologically mediated it is crucial to acknowledge that changes to infrastructures and technologies might reconfigure individuals’ interpretations of values, meanings, competences and, in turn, their practices (Shove Ea, 2003).

Regulations and changes in material structures, such as those enabled by technological innovation in lighting and ventilation, have the potential to construct more sustainable practices related to indoor comfort (Shove E., 2003). But this process can be inhibited if previous practices filled with socially shared meanings, competences and values are not taken into account (i.e. lights do not only illuminate but also create ambience and safety (Crosbie and Guy, 2008); airing rooms in the morning is perceived as healthy (DellaValle et al., 2018)).

Also, when accounted for, social practices might explain several phenomena, like the prebound effect. As an example, the energy poor might moderate the effects of heat (cold) by performing a range of practices that are often ignored in the one-size-fits-all response with appliances (Strengers and Maller, 2011). As a result, the energy poor might consume far less energy than predicted by techno-centric estimates(i.e. they are forced to underheat (undercool) their homes to save money (Sunikka-Blank and Galvin, 2012)).

Social Classes

Another prominent social structure is social class. The class, determined by the individual’s resources (capital)15, produces a character (i.e. dispositions, sense of self) (habitus) that elicits certain behaviours in the social reality (fields) where agents seek profit or status (Bourdieu, 1987). The primary class division is between those who have high and low total capital (Bourdieu, 1987). According to the social theories of vertical and horizontal diffusion (Bartiaux et al., 2016), highly visible practices16 (such as installing solar panels (Keirstead, 2007)) diffuse from the upper to the middle and the lower class for status concerns (Bartiaux, 2008). The vertical diffusion of status has been applied to explain the adoption of socially visible and costly energy-saving practices, wherein lower class individuals, who wish to ascend to a higher class, adopt practices usually performed by the upper class (McMeekin and Tomlinson, 1997; Jensen, 2005; Bartiaux, 2008).

Conversely, non-visible practices (such as insulating one’s home) diffuse horizontally, namely they diffuse among individuals connected in the same network (Rogers, 2010), through casual conversation, and thanks to reciprocal feeling of trust (Berelson et al., 1968). In particular, interpersonal communication can boost both energy conservation behaviours (Yavas and Riecken, 1981; Shama, 1983), and engagement in EE (Emirbayer and Mische, 1998; McMichael and Shipworth, 2013).

Understanding how EE investments diffuse across and within social classes can help advance justice-aware energy policy (Sovacool et al., 2017), by allowing for more comprehensive policy choices (Sovacool and Dworkin, 2015). As an example, costly non-visible practices (such as insulating one’s home) might not diffuse easily horizontally among lower classes because of unequal access to finance and information (e.g. they face more hurdles due to power and cognitive constrains in the acquisition of information and subsidies (DellaValle and Sareen, 2020)). To avoid policies worsening these inequalities, it is thus crucial to adopt a lens capturing the connection between social classes and justice (Sovacool, 2021). As an example, renovation projects that disregard potential distributional effects might yield the “renoviction” effect: lower class households are more likely to live in energy-inefficient houses (Poortinga et al., 2003) but after renovation they become less affordable, and households are forced to dislocate to more affordable but less efficient housing (Grossmann, 2019).

Discussion

The dominant problem in contemporary EE policy is framed as a one of individual choice (Lutzenhiser, 2014). Such a frame positions policy makers as enablers, whose role is to create the conditions for citizens to optimally invest in EE (Shove, 2010). Within this frame, policy makers face the challenge to identify which insights from the available scientific knowledge are more appropriate to reach the objective of “closing the EE gap” by changing behaviour (Schubert and Stadelmann, 2015). However, this particular representation of the EE problem may not be as socially relevant as it could be.

At the same time, this frame positions the insights from economics and behavioural sciences as useful at identifying factors underlying the EE gap, and those from sociology at “taking social norms a bit more seriously as influences on behaviour” ((Jackson, 2005), p.55).

As suggested by Whitmarsh et al. (Whitmarsh et al., 2011), the fact that concept of practices reminds that action is partly due to norms and institutions suggests a point of intersection between sociological and individualizing approaches (i.e. behavioural sciences also acknowledge that social norms and identities affect behaviour (Whitmarsh et al., 2011)). This puts forward the possibility to integrate these different perspectives and to address more effectively the problem of the EE gap, something that has already proven successful in the contexts of energy consumption and sustainable transition (Nye et al., 2010). The constructivist paradigm underlying the sociological perspective highlights that reality and problems, including the EE gap issue, can be socially constructed (Harris, 2013).

By bringing about unique perspectives that enable to see a problem from different angles (Whitmarsh et al., 2011), the fundamental differences between sociology, economics and behavioural sciences enable to better capture the complexity surrounding EE. As an example, by focusing on the types of heuristics that individuals use to make decisions under complexity, the behavioural science perspective may help policy-makers become aware whether their perceptions of social problems are accurate or whether they form judgements about citizens’ needs overrelying on specific heuristics or interpretations of the world (Bergan and Fitzpatrick, 2021). The constructivist paradigm underlying the sociological perspective highlights that reality and problems, including the EE gap issue, can be socially constructed (Harris, 2013).

For example, citizens’ experiences, values and meanings connected with their homes might shape their understanding about how to achieve coolth and warmth (Chersoni et al., forthcoming; Harputlugil and de Wilde, 2021), e.g. the energy poor might perform a range of practices to moderate the effects of heat (cold) (Strengers and Maller, 2011). Disregarding these needs and practices will lead to dismiss critical factors useful not only to determine what is relevant to solve the problem (e.g. How to promote the uptake of renovation and other EE measures?), but also for a better understanding of the problem itself (e.g. Is EE the only solution to improve comfort?). Therefore, to give EE policy advice more scientific validity and more social relevance, it is paramount to be mindful of which evidence is used in EE policy making. Practically, to make political decisions that are scientifically valid and socially relevant, policy makers can initiate a reflexive process that closely examines the paradigms of current policy agendas through the lenses of different social science perspectives, with representatives of different social sciences disciplines. This process will not only enable them to become more aware of the different intellectual resources but also of the different societal perspectives that could inform policy solutions and provide additional evidence about society’s needs (Funtowicz and Ravetz, 1993).

There are, however, challenges that need to be considered. As an example, scientists need to engage in critical thinking to become aware of their disciplinary guiding epistemological assumptions and methodological practices (Ramadier, 2004). While these challenges might keep this call an unfulfilled project, practical examples suggest that in some contexts there are examples of progress along these lines. In particular, there have been attempts to nurture critical thinking - through the implementation of strategies fostering multi-disciplinary collaborations across teams (Pereira and Saltelli, 2017) and conversations challenging current narratives.

Conclusion

The Climate Change challenge calls for a swift reduction of energy consumption. One way to achieve this is through increased energy efficiency.

So far the debate on how to encourage energy efficiency has been guided by scientific insights that help understand how to remove barriers and promote drivers of the decision to optimally invest in EE.

Only recently, the integration of the human factor started being integrated into energy efficiency policy, complementing the physical–technical–economic approach, which has a strong focus on technologies and cost savings.

However, not only the integration of the human factor through the use of social sciences is at its infancy, but also the representation of the problem of EE adoption only as a problem of individual choice might be partial and socially irrelevant.

While the perspectives taken by economics and behavioural sciences enable to capture the individual dimension of energy efficiency as a problem of individual choice, the collective and social aspect of energy efficiency is still largely overlooked on the EE policy agenda.

By using a narrative review approach, this paper presented key energy-related social science concepts, to increase policy makers’ awareness of complementary disciplinary resources, on which they can draw to better define and address the problems associated to EE. First, it presents sociology as an approach that complements the dominant economic-behavioural science one, which policy makers can draw from to better define and address the problems associated to EE. In particular, by highlighting that problems can be socially constructed, the sociological perspective warns that as social structures interpenetrate individual actions and construction of reality, EE policy needs to look beyond barriers, market and behavioural failures.

Second, this paper highlighted the need for a critical account of evidence use in EE policy, and that an interdisciplinary endeavour, through the exploitation of insights from complementary social sciences, is likely to give policy advice more scientific validity and more social relevance. While developing such an approach is not free from challenges, some promising examples suggest that this project could already be tested in some contexts.

To accomplish the goal of translating different theoretical insights in a workable way for policy makers, this paper synthetized different academic works using the narrative review approach. Because of that, the resulting findings could be biased towards the authors’ experience in the field (Sovacool et al., 2018). Therefore, future research should adopt other methodologies, such as expert interviews with representatives of different disciplines. This would also enable to better explore the feasibility of such an interdisciplinary endeavour.

Author Contributions

Conception and design of study: NDV and PB. Writing—Original Draft: NDV. Writing—Review and Editing: PB.

Funding

The author has not received any funding for this research, it is part of his job.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Footnotes

1https://www.ipcc.ch/sr15/chapter/chapter-4/.

2https://www.iea.org/reports/energy-efficiency-2020.

3https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX%3A52011DC0885.

4https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/european-green-deal-communication_en.pdf.

5The paper does not focus on organizations.

6i.e. the disciplines that systematically study human behaviour, such as behavioural economics and psychology.

7i.e. deviations from the assumptions of rational choice (Shogren and Taylor, 2008).

8i.e., individuals evaluate decision outcomes in terms of gains and losses relative to a reference point, usually the status quo, and evaluate losses to be larger than equal-sized gains(Tversky and Kahneman, 1979, 1981).

9i.e., a tendency to choose options that maintain the current situation.

10i.e. individuals receive a positive emotional response from the mere act of adopting measures that benefit the environment.

11i.e. individuals care about the level of actual environmental protection achieved.

12i.e. individuals are willing to protect the environment because they think it is a good way to comply with the scripts of their identity.

13i.e. individuals think that their relevant group thinks it is appropriate to protect the environment, and anticipate social disapproval if they decide otherwise.

14i.e. interventions that target “any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people’s behaviour in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives” (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008).

15a social group that is defined in a social space by the quantity and the proportion of available social, cultural and economic resources (Bourdieu, 1987).

16Practices are here understood as practices that involve consumption, conservation, or generation of energy, as synonymous of behaviour, rather than social practices.

References

Ajzen, I. (1991). The Theory of Planned Behavior. Organizational Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 50 (2), 179–211. doi:10.1016/0749-5978(91)90020-t

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Akerlof, G. A., and Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and Identity*. Q. J. Econ. 115 (3), 715–753. doi:10.1162/003355300554881

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Alberini, A., Banfi, S., and Ramseier, C. (2013). Energy Efficiency Investments in the Home: Swiss Homeowners and Expectations About Future Energy Prices. Energ. J. 34 (1), 3. doi:10.5547/01956574.34.1.3

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Aliyu, A. A., Bello, M. U., Kasim, R., and Martin, D. (2014). Positivist and Non-positivist Paradigm in Social Science Research: Conflicting Paradigms or Perfect Partners. J. Mgmt. Sustainability 4, 79. doi:10.5539/jms.v4n3p79

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Allcott, H., and Greenstone, M. (2012). Is There an Energy Efficiency Gap. J. Econ. Perspect. 26 (1), 3–28. doi:10.1257/jep.26.1.3

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Alvesson, M., and Skoldberg, K. (2009). Positivism, Social Constructionism, Critical Realism: Three Reference Points in the Philosophy of Science. Reflexive Methodol. New Vistas Qual. Res., 15–52.

Google Scholar

Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence. J. Polit. Economy 97 (6), 1447–1458. doi:10.1086/261662

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ateş, H. (2020). Merging Theory of Planned Behavior and Value Identity Personal Norm Model to Explain Pro-environmental Behaviors. Sustainable Prod. Consumption 24, 169–180. doi:10.1016/j.spc.2020.07.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Axon, S., Morrissey, J., Aiesha, R., Hillman, J., Revez, A., Lennon, B., et al. (2018). The Human Factor: Classification of European Community-Based Behaviour Change Initiatives. J. Clean. Prod. 182, 567–586. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.01.232

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Baggio, M., Ciriolo, E., Marandola, G., and van Bavel, R. (2021). The Evolution of Behaviourally Informed Policy-Making in the EU. J. Eur. Public Pol. 28, 658. doi:10.1080/13501763.2021.1912145

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ballinger, T. P., Palumbo, M. G., and Wilcox, N. T. (2003). Precautionary Saving and Social Learning Across Generations: An Experiment. Econ. J. 113 (490), 920–947. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.t01-1-00158

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bartiaux, F. (2008). Changing Energy-Related Practices and Behaviours in the Residential Sector: Sociological Approaches, 6. Madrid: Efonet Workshop “Behavioural Changes-Backcasting and Future Trends”.

Google Scholar

Bartiaux, F., Schmidt, L., Horta, A., and Correia, A. (2016). Social Diffusion of Energy-Related Practices and Representations: Patterns and Policies in Portugal and Belgium. Energy Policy 88, 413–421. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2015.10.046

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Batel, S., Castro, P., Devine‐Wright, P., and Howarth, C. (2016). Developing a Critical Agenda to Understand Pro‐environmental Actions: Contributions from Social Representations and Social Practices Theories. Wires Clim. Change 7 (5), 727–745. doi:10.1002/wcc.417

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Belaïd, F., and Joumni, H. (2020). Behavioral Attitudes Towards Energy Saving: Empirical Evidence from France. Energy Policy 140, 111406. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111406

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Belaïd, F., Youssef, A. B., and Lazaric, N. (2020). Scrutinizing the Direct Rebound Effect for French Households Using Quantile Regression and Data from an Original Survey. Ecol. Econ. 176, 106755. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2020.106755

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bénabou, R., and Tirole, J. (2006). Incentives and Prosocial Behavior. Am. Econ. Rev. 96 (5), 1652–1678. doi:10.1257/aer.96.5.1652

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Berelson, B., Gaudet, H., and Lazarsfeld, P. F. (1968). The People’s Choice: How the Voter Makes up His Mind in a Presidential Campaign. Columbia University Press.

Google Scholar

Bergan, D. E., and Fitzpatrick, N. (2021). Policymaker Perceptions of Citizen Needs: Heuristics, Accuracy, and Partisan Differences. Behav. Public Pol., 1–29. doi:10.1017/bpp.2020.62

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bertoldi, P., Economidou, M., Palermo, V., Boza-Kiss, B., and Todeschi, V. (2021). How to Finance Energy Renovation of Residential Buildings: Review of Current and Emerging Financing Instruments in the EU. Brussels: Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Energy and Environment, e384.

Google Scholar

Bertoldi, P. (2020). “Overview of the European Union Policies to Promote More Sustainable Behaviours in Energy End-Users,” in Energy and Behaviour. Editors M. Lopes, C. Henggler Antunes, and K. B. Janda (Academic Press, Elsevier), 451–477. doi:10.1016/b978-0-12-818567-4.00018-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bertoldi, P., Rezessy, S., and Oikonomou, V. (2013). Rewarding Energy Savings Rather Than Energy Efficiency: Exploring the Concept of a Feed-In Tariff for Energy Savings. Energy Policy 56, 526–535. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.019

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Bicchieri, C. (2005). The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms. Cambridge University Press.

Google Scholar

Blasch, J., and Daminato, C. (2020). Behavioral Anomalies and Energy-Related Individual Choices: The Role of Status-Quo Bias. Energ. J. 41 (6). doi:10.5547/01956574.41.6.jbla

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Blasch, J., Filippini, M., Kumar, N., and Martinez-Cruz, A. L. (2017). Narrowing the Energy Efficiency gap: The Impact of Educational Programs, Online Support Tools and Energy-Related Investment Literacy. Online Support Tools and Energy-Related Investment Literacy.

Google Scholar

Bourdieu, P. (1987). What Makes a Social Class? on the Theoretical and Practical Existence of Groups. Berkeley J. Sociol. 32, 1–17.

Google Scholar

Brosch, T., Patel, M. K., and Sander, D. (2014). Affective Influences on Energy-Related Decisions and Behaviors. Front. Energ. Res. 2, 11. doi:10.3389/fenrg.2014.00011

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Brown, M. A. (2001). Market Failures and Barriers as a Basis for Clean Energy Policies. Energy Policy 29 (14), 1197–1207. doi:10.1016/s0301-4215(01)00067-2

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioural Studies of Strategic Thinking in Games. Trends Cogn. Sci. 7 (5), 225–231. doi:10.1016/s1364-6613(03)00094-9

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cass, N., and Shove, E. (2018). Standards? Whose Standards. Architectural Sci. Rev. 61 (5), 272–279. doi:10.1080/00038628.2018.1502158

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cattaneo, C. (2019). Internal and External Barriers to Energy Efficiency: Which Role for Policy Interventions. Energy Efficiency 12, 1293–1311. doi:10.1007/s12053-019-09775-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chersoni, G., DellaValle, N., and Fontana, M. (forthcoming). Improving Policy Design for Energy Efficiency: An Encompassing Framework. Energy Policy.

Google Scholar

Cialdini, R. B., and Goldstein, N. J. (2004). Social Influence: Compliance and Conformity. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 55, 591–621. doi:10.1146/annurev.psych.55.090902.142015

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cialdini, R. B., Kallgren, C. A., and Reno, R. R. (1991). A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: A Theoretical Refinement and Reevaluation of the Role of Norms in Human Behavior. Adv. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 24, 201–234. doi:10.1016/s0065-2601(08)60330-5

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Cialdini, R. B., Reno, R. R., and Kallgren, C. A. (1990). A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: Recycling the Concept of Norms to Reduce Littering in Public Places. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 58 (6), 1015–1026. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.1015

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Crosbie, T., and Guy, S. (2008). En’lightening’energy Use: The Co-evolution of Household Lighting Practices. Int. J. Environ. Tech. Manag. 9 (2–3), 220–235. doi:10.1504/ijetm.2008.019035

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

De Groot, J. I. M., and Steg, L. (2010). Relationships between Value Orientations, Self-Determined Motivational Types and Pro-environmental Behavioural Intentions. J. Environ. Psychol. 30 (4), 368–378. doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2010.04.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

DellaValle, N., Bisello, A., and Balest, J. (2018). In Search of Behavioural and Social Levers for Effective Social Housing Retrofit Programs. Energy and Buildings 172, 517–524. doi:10.1016/j.enbuild.2018.05.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

DellaValle, N., and Sareen, S. (2020). Nudging and Boosting for Equity? towards a Behavioural Economics of Energy justice. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 68, 101589. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101589

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. J. Econ. Lit. 47 (2), 315–372. doi:10.1257/jel.47.2.315

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

DiMaggio, P. (1997). Culture and Cognition. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 23 (1), 263–287. doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.23.1.263

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dütschke, E., Frondel, M., Schleich, J., and Vance, C. (2018). Moral Licensing—Another Source of Rebound. Front. Energ. Res. 6, 38.

Google Scholar

Economidou, M., Todeschi, V., Bertoldi, P., D'Agostino, D., Zangheri, P., and Castellazzi, L. (2020). Review of 50 Years of EU Energy Efficiency Policies for Buildings. Energy and Buildings 225, 110322. doi:10.1016/j.enbuild.2020.110322

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Elster, J. (1989). The Cement of Society: A Survey of Social Order. Cambridge University Press.

Google Scholar

Emirbayer, M., and Mische, A. (1998). What Is agency. Am. J. Sociol. 103 (4), 962–1023. doi:10.1086/231294

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Fawcett, T., and Killip, G. (2019). Re-thinking Energy Efficiency in European Policy: Practitioners' Use of 'multiple Benefits' Arguments. J. Clean. Prod. 210, 1171–1179. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.026

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Festinger, L. (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Vol. 2. Stanford University Press.

Google Scholar

Foulds, C., and Robison, R. (2018). Advancing Energy Policy: Lessons on the Integration of Social Sciences and Humanities. Springer Nature.

Google Scholar

Frey, B. S., and others, (1997). Not Just for the Money.

Google Scholar

Frey, B. S., and Stutzer, A. (2006). Environmental Morale and Motivation.

Google Scholar

Frondel, M., and Lohmann, S. (2011). The European Commission's Light Bulb Decree: Another Costly Regulation. Energy Policy 39 (6), 3177–3181. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.02.072

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Funtowicz, S. O., and Ravetz, J. R. (1993). Science for the post-normal Age. Futures 25 (7), 739–755. doi:10.1016/0016-3287(93)90022-l

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Galvin, R. (2020). Who Co-opted Our Energy Efficiency Gains? A Sociology of Macro-Level Rebound Effects and US Car Makers. Energy Policy 142, 111548. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111548

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Giddens, A. (1979). Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure, and Contradiction in Social Analysis, 241. Univ of California Press.

Google Scholar

Giddens, A. (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Univ of California Press.

Google Scholar

Gillingham, K., Harding, M., and Rapson, D. (2012). Split Incentives in Residential Energy Consumption. Energ. J. 33 (2). doi:10.5547/01956574.33.2.3

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gillingham, K., Newell, R. G., and Palmer, K. (2009). Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 1 (1), 597–620. doi:10.1146/annurev.resource.102308.124234

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gillingham, K., and Palmer, K. (2014). Bridging the Energy Efficiency Gap: Policy Insights from Economic Theory and Empirical Evidence. Rev. Environ. Econ. Pol. 8 (1), 18–38. doi:10.1093/reep/ret021

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gillingham, K., and Tsvetanov, T. (2018). Nudging Energy Efficiency Audits: Evidence from a Field experiment. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 90, 303–316. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2018.06.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Gneezy, U., and Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay Enough or Don't Pay at All*. Q. J. Econ. 115 (3), 791–810. doi:10.1162/003355300554917

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Golove, W. H., and Eto, J. H. (1996). Market Barriers to Energy Efficiency: A Critical Reappraisal of the Rationale for Public Policies to Promote Energy Efficiency. Berkeley, CA: Lawrence Berkeley Lab.

Google Scholar

Griskevicius, V., Tybur, J. M., and Van den Bergh, B. (2010). Going green to Be Seen: Status, Reputation, and Conspicuous Conservation. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 98 (3), 392–404. doi:10.1037/a0017346

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Grossmann, K. (2019). Energy Efficiency for Whom? A Conceptual View on Retrofitting, Residential Segregation and the Housing Market. Energy Efficiency for Whom, 78–95. doi:10.3280/sur2019-119006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Grüne-Yanoff, T., and Hertwig, R. (2016). Nudge versus Boost: How Coherent Are Policy and Theory. Minds and Machines 26 (1–2), 149–183. doi:10.1007/s11023-015-9367-9

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Guimarães Pereira, Â., and Saltelli, A. (2017). Post-normal Institutional Identities: Quality Assurance, Reflexivity and Ethos of Care. Futures 91, 53–61. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2016.11.009

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hards, S. K. (2013). Status, Stigma and Energy Practices in the Home. Local Environ. 18 (4), 438–454. doi:10.1080/13549839.2012.748731

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hargreaves, T., and Middlemiss, L. (2020). The Importance of Social Relations in Shaping Energy Demand. Nat. Energ. 1–7, 195–201. doi:10.1038/s41560-020-0553-5

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Harputlugil, T., and de Wilde, P. (2021). The Interaction between Humans and Buildings for Energy Efficiency: A Critical Review. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 71, 101828. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101828

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Harris, S. R. (2013). “Studying the Construction of Social Problems,” in Making Sense of Social Problems: New Images, New Issues, 1–9.

Google Scholar

Hassett, K. A., and Metcalf, G. E. (1995). Energy Tax Credits and Residential Conservation Investment: Evidence from Panel Data. J. Public Econ. 57 (2), 201–217. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(94)01452-t

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Heiner, R. (2002). Social Problems: An Introduction to Critical Constructionism. New York: Oxford University Press.

Google Scholar

Hertwig, R., and Ryall, M. D. (2020). Nudge versus Boost: Agency Dynamics under Libertarian Paternalism. Econ. J. 130 (629), 1384–1415. doi:10.1093/ej/uez054

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hertwig, R. (2017). When to Consider Boosting: Some Rules for Policy-Makers. Behav. Public Pol. 1 (2), 143–161. doi:10.1017/bpp.2016.14

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Heutel, G. (2019). Prospect Theory and Energy Efficiency. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 96, 236–254. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2019.06.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hilton, D., Charalambides, L., Demarque, C., Waroquier, L., and Raux, C. (2014). A Tax Can Nudge: The Impact of an Environmentally Motivated Bonus/malus Fiscal System on Transport Preferences. J. Econ. Psychol. 42, 17–27. doi:10.1016/j.joep.2014.02.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hirst, E., and Brown, M. (1990). Closing the Efficiency Gap: Barriers to the Efficient Use of Energy. Resour. Conservation Recycling 3 (4), 267–281. doi:10.1016/0921-3449(90)90023-w

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hitchings, R., and Shu Jun Lee, S. J. (2008). Air Conditioning and the Material Culture of Routine Human Encasement. J. Mater. Cult. 13 (3), 251–265. doi:10.1177/1359183508095495

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Hoff, K., and Stiglitz, J. E. (2016). Striving for Balance in Economics: Towards a Theory of the Social Determination of Behavior. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 126, 25–57. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2016.01.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ingold, T. (2011). Being Alive: Essays on Movement, Knowledge and Description. Taylor & Francis.

Google Scholar

Jackson, T. (2005). Motivating Sustainable Consumption. Sust. Develop. Res. Netw. 29 (1), 30–40.

Google Scholar

Jaffe, A. B., and Stavins, R. N. (1994). The Energy-Efficiency gap what Does it Mean. Energy Policy 22 (10), 804–810. doi:10.1016/0301-4215(94)90138-4

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Jensen, O. M. (2005). “Consumer Inertia to Energy Saving,” in ECEEE Summer Study Proceedings, Mandelieu la Napoule.

Google Scholar

Keirstead, J. (2007). Behavioural Responses to Photovoltaic Systems in the UK Domestic Sector. Energy Policy 35 (8), 4128–4141. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2007.02.019

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Labanca, N., and Bertoldi, P. (2018). Beyond Energy Efficiency and Individual Behaviours: Policy Insights from Social Practice Theories. Energy Policy 115, 494–502. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2018.01.027

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lennon, B., Dunphy, N., Gaffney, C., Revez, A., Mullally, G., and O’Connor, P. (2020). Citizen or Consumer? Reconsidering Energy Citizenship. J. Environ. Pol. Plann. 22 (2), 184–197. doi:10.1080/1523908x.2019.1680277

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Loewenstein, G., and Chater, N. (2017). Putting Nudges in Perspective. Behav. Public Pol. 1 (1), 26–53. doi:10.1017/bpp.2016.7

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lopes, M. A. R., Antunes, C. H., and Martins, N. (2012). Energy Behaviours as Promoters of Energy Efficiency: A 21st Century Review. Renew. Sust. Energ. Rev. 16 (6), 4095–4104. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2012.03.034

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lutzenhiser, L. (1993). Social and Behavioral Aspects of Energy Use. Annu. Rev. Energ. Environ. 18 (1), 247–289. doi:10.1146/annurev.eg.18.110193.001335

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Lutzenhiser, L. (2014). Through the Energy Efficiency Looking Glass. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 1, 141–151. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2014.03.011

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Madrian, B. C. (2014). Applying Insights from Behavioral Economics to Policy Design. Annu. Rev. Econ. 6 (1), 663–688. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-080213-041033

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mauser, W., Klepper, G., Rice, M., Schmalzbauer, B. S., Hackmann, H., Leemans, R., et al. (2013). Transdisciplinary Global Change Research: The Co-creation of Knowledge for Sustainability. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustainability 5 (3–4), 420–431. doi:10.1016/j.cosust.2013.07.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

McMeekin, A., and Tomlinson, M. (1997). The Diffusion of Household Durables in the UK. Centre for Research on Innovation and Competition, University of Manchester.

Google Scholar

McMichael, M., and Shipworth, D. (2013). The Value of Social Networks in the Diffusion of Energy-Efficiency Innovations in UK Households. Energy Policy 53, 159–168. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.10.039

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Monin, B., and Jordan, A. H. (2009). “The Dynamic Moral Self: A Social Psychological Perspective,” in Personality, Identity, and Character: Explorations in Moral Psychology, 341–354.

Google Scholar

Münscher, R., Vetter, M., and Scheuerle, T. (2016). A Review and Taxonomy of Choice Architecture Techniques. J. Behav. Decis. Making 29 (5), 511–524. doi:10.1002/bdm.1897

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nauclér, T., and Enkvist, P.-A. (2009). Pathways to a Low-Carbon Economy: Version 2 of the Global Greenhouse Gas Abatement Cost Curve. McKinsey & Company 192 (3).

Google Scholar

Newell, R. G., and Siikamäki, J. (2014). Nudging Energy Efficiency Behavior: The Role of Information Labels. J. Assoc. Environ. Resource Economists 1 (4), 555–598. doi:10.1086/679281

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nordlund, A. M., and Garvill, J. (2002). Value Structures behind Proenvironmental Behavior. Environ. Behav. 34 (6), 740–756. doi:10.1177/001391602237244

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Nye, M., Whitmarsh, L., and Foxon, T. (2010). Sociopsychological Perspectives on the Active Roles of Domestic Actors in Transition to a Lower Carbon Electricity Economy. Environ. Plan. A. 42 (3), 697–714. doi:10.1068/a4245

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Palm, J., and Reindl, K. (2018). Understanding Barriers to Energy-Efficiency Renovations of Multifamily Dwellings. Energy Efficiency 11 (1), 53–65. doi:10.1007/s12053-017-9549-9

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Poortinga, W., Steg, L., Vlek, C., and Wiersma, G. (2003). Household Preferences for Energy-Saving Measures: A Conjoint Analysis. J. Econ. Psychol. 24 (1), 49–64. doi:10.1016/s0167-4870(02)00154-x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Ramadier, T. (2004). Transdisciplinarity and its Challenges: The Case of Urban Studies. Futures 36 (4), 423–439. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2003.10.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Rogers, E. M. (2010). Diffusion of Innovations. Simon & Schuster.

Google Scholar

Ruzzenenti, F., and Bertoldi, P. (2017). “Energy Conservation Policies in the Light of the Energetics of Evolution,” in Complex Systems and Social Practices in Energy Transitions (Springer), 147–167. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-33753-1_7

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sacco, P., and Zarri, L. (2003). Complessità motivazionale, interazione strategica e gestione del conflitto. Etica Ed. Economia 1 (2), 73–89.

Google Scholar

Sanstad, A. H., and Howarth, R. B. (1994). 'Normal' Markets, Market Imperfections and Energy Efficiency. Energy Policy 22 (10), 811–818. doi:10.1016/0301-4215(94)90139-2

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Schleich, J., Faure, C., and Meissner, T. (2019). “Adoption of Retrofit Measures Among home-owners in EU Countries: The Effects of Access to Capital and Debt Aversion,” in Working Paper Sustainability and Innovation.

Google Scholar

Schleich, J., Gassmann, X., Faure, C., and Meissner, T. (2016). Making the Implicit Explicit: A Look inside the Implicit Discount Rate. Energy Policy 97, 321–331. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.07.044

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Schubert, R., and Stadelmann, M. (2015). Energy-Using Durables €" Why Consumers Refrain from Economically Optimal Choices. Front. Energ. Res. 3, 7. doi:10.3389/fenrg.2015.00007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shama, A. (1983). Energy Conservation in US Buildings. Energy Policy 11 (2), 148–167. doi:10.1016/0301-4215(83)90027-7

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shogren, J. F., and Taylor, L. O. (2008). On Behavioral-Environmental Economics. Rev. Environ. Econ. Pol. 2 (1), 26–44. doi:10.1093/reep/rem027

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shove, E. (2010). Beyond the ABC: Climate Change Policy and Theories of Social Change. Environ. Plan. A. 42 (6), 1273–1285. doi:10.1068/a42282

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shove, E., and Pantzar, M. (2005). Consumers, Producers and Practices. J. Consumer Cult. 5 (1), 43–64. doi:10.1177/1469540505049846

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shove, E., Pantzar, M., and Watson, M. (2012). The Dynamics of Social Practice: Everyday Life and How it Changes. Sage.

Google Scholar

Shove, E, E. (2003). Converging Conventions of comfort, Cleanliness and Convenience. J. Consumer Pol. 26 (4), 395–418. doi:10.1023/a:1026362829781

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Shove, Ea, E. A. (2003). Comfort, Cleanliness and Convenience: The Social Organization of Normality. Oxford: Berg Publishers.

Google Scholar

Simon, H. A. (1955). A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Q. J. Econ. 69 (1), 99–118. doi:10.2307/1884852

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of Man; Social and Rational.

Google Scholar

Sousa Lourenco, J., Ciriolo, E., Rafael Rodrigues Viera De Almeida, S., and Troussard, X. (2016). Behavioural Insights Applied to Policy—European Report 2016. Brussels: Publications Office of the European Union.

Google Scholar

Sovacool, B. K., Axsen, J., and Sorrell, S. (2018). Promoting Novelty, Rigor, and Style in Energy Social Science: Towards Codes of Practice for Appropriate Methods and Research Design. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 45, 12–42. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2018.07.007

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sovacool, B. K., Burke, M., Baker, L., Kotikalapudi, C. K., and Wlokas, H. (2017). New Frontiers and Conceptual Frameworks for Energy Justice. Energy Policy 105, 677–691. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2017.03.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sovacool, B. K., and Dworkin, M. H. (2015). Energy justice: Conceptual Insights and Practical Applications. Appl. Energ. 142, 435–444. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2015.01.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sovacool, B. K., Ryan, S. E., Stern, P. C., Janda, K., Rochlin, G., Spreng, D., et al. (2015). Integrating Social Science in Energy Research. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 6, 95–99. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2014.12.005

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sovacool, B. K. (2021). Who Are the Victims of Low-Carbon Transitions? Towards a Political Ecology of Climate Change Mitigation. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 73, 101916. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2021.101916

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Stadelmann, M. (2017). Mind the Gap? Critically Reviewing the Energy Efficiency Gap with Empirical Evidence. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 27, 117–128. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2017.03.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Steg, L., and Vlek, C. (2009). Encouraging Pro-environmental Behaviour: An Integrative Review and Research Agenda. J. Environ. Psychol. 29 (3), 309–317. doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2008.10.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Stern, N., and Stern, N. H. (2007). The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge University Press.

Google Scholar

Stern, P. C., and Dietz, T. (1994). The Value Basis of Environmental Concern. J. Soc. Issues 50 (3), 65–84. doi:10.1111/j.1540-4560.1994.tb02420.x

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Stern, P. C. (2000). New Environmental Theories: Toward a Coherent Theory of Environmentally Significant Behavior. J. Soc. Isssues 56 (3), 407–424. doi:10.1111/0022-4537.00175

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Strengers, Y., and Maller, C. (2011). Integrating Health, Housing and Energy Policies: Social Practices of Cooling. Building Res. Inf. 39 (2), 154–168. doi:10.1080/09613218.2011.562720

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sunikka-Blank, M., and Galvin, R. (2012). Introducing the Prebound Effect: The Gap Between Performance and Actual Energy Consumption. Building Res. Inf. 40 (3), 260–273. doi:10.1080/09613218.2012.690952

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Taylor, P. G., d’Ortigue, O. L., Francoeur, M., and Trudeau, N. (2010). Final Energy Use in IEA Countries: The Role of Energy Efficiency. Energy Policy 38 (11), 6463–6474. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.05.009

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health. Wealth, and Happiness, 6.

Google Scholar

Tietenberg, T. (2009). Reflections-Energy Efficiency Policy: Pipe Dream or Pipeline to the Future. Rev. Environ. Econ. Pol. 3 (2), 304–320. doi:10.1093/reep/rep004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tsemekidi Tzeiranaki, S., Bertoldi, P., Diluiso, F., Castellazzi, L., Economidou, M., Labanca, N., et al. (2019). Analysis of the EU Residential Energy Consumption: Trends and Determinants. Energies 12 (6), 1065. doi:10.3390/en12061065

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tsvetanov, T., and Segerson, K. (2014). The Welfare Effects of Energy Efficiency Standards when Choice Sets Matter. J. Assoc. Environ. Resource Economists 1 (1/2), 233–271. doi:10.1086/676036

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Science 185 (4157), 1124–1131. doi:10.1126/science.185.4157.1124

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1979). Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 47 (2), 263–291.

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1981). The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice. Science 211 (4481), 453–458. doi:10.1126/science.7455683

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Warde, A. (2005). Consumption and Theories of Practice. J. Consumer Cult. 5 (2), 131–153. doi:10.1177/1469540505053090

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wesley Schultz, P. (2001). The Structure of Environmental Concern: Concern for Self, Other People, and the Biosphere. J. Environ. Psychol. 21 (4), 327–339. doi:10.1006/jevp.2001.0227

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wesley Schultz, P., and Zelezny, L. (1999). Values as Predictors of Environmental Attitudes: Evidence for Consistency Across 14 Countries. J. Environ. Psychol. 19 (3), 255–265. doi:10.1006/jevp.1999.0129

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Whitmarsh, L., O'Neill, S., and Lorenzoni, I. (2011). Climate Change or Social Change? Debate Within, Amongst, and beyond Disciplines. Environ. Plan. A. 43 (2), 258–261. doi:10.1068/a43359

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wilhite, H., and Lutzenhiser, L. (1999). Social Loading and Sustainable Consumption. ACR North American Advances.

Google Scholar

Wilhite, H., Shove, E., Lutzenhiser, L., and Kempton, W. (2000). “Twenty Years of Energy Demand Management: We Know More About Individual Behavior but How Much Do We Really Know about Demand,” in Proceeding from the ACEEE, 435–453.

Google Scholar

Wilson, C., Crane, L., and Chryssochoidis, G. (2015). Why Do Homeowners Renovate Energy Efficiently? Contrasting Perspectives and Implications for Policy. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 7, 12–22. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2015.03.002

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wilson, C., and Dowlatabadi, H. (2007). Models of Decision Making and Residential Energy Use. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 32, 169–203. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.32.053006.141137

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Yavas, U., and Riecken, G. (1981). Stimulating Energy Conservation the Use of the Opinion Leadership Process. Energy Policy 9 (3), 226–231. doi:10.1016/0301-4215(81)90078-1

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: energy policy, economics, sociology, behavioural sciences, interdisciplinarity

Citation: Della Valle N and Bertoldi P (2022) Promoting Energy Efficiency: Barriers, Societal Needs and Policies. Front. Energy Res. 9:804091. doi: 10.3389/fenrg.2021.804091

Received: 28 October 2021; Accepted: 23 December 2021;
Published: 09 February 2022.

Edited by:

Fateh Belaid, King Abdullah Petroleum Studies and Research Center (KAPSARC), Saudi Arabia

Reviewed by:

Rita Werle, Impact Energy AG, Switzerland
Isam Shahrour, Université de Lille, France

Copyright © 2022 Della Valle and Bertoldi. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Paolo Bertoldi, cGFvbG8uYmVydG9sZGlAZWMuZXVyb3BhLmV1

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.